BRITAIN's BALANCE-OF-PAYMENT PROBLEM AND THE DEVALUATION OF 1949 ffHIS IS AN ORIGINAL MANUSCRIPT ffT MAY NOT BE COPIED WITHOUT THE AUTHOR’S PERMISSION BRITAIN’S BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS PROBLEM AND THE DEVALUATION OF 1949 by EZEKIEL GALLEGOS ESQUEDA, B.A. THESIS Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School of The University of Texas in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements For the Degree of MASTER OF ARTS THE UNIVERSITY OP TEXAS June 1952 PREFACE The magnitude of the problem which is examined in the following pages demands a more penetrating analysis than this writer has been able to make. The problem contains too many imponderable factors and raises too unanswer­ many able questions; yet, its very complexity poses a challenge which the inquiring mind cannot easily turn down. Although aware of the enormity of the task and, especially, of his own limitations, this writer has, none the less, undertaken the preparation of this paper in the hope of presenting the general aspects of the problem in terms that can be readily grasped. The British balance-of-payments problem appears to defy not only permanent solution, but, at this time, also precise analysis. This study does not offer a solution, does it seek one. It merely describes the nature of nor the problem and its impact on Britain 1 s external financial position. This study does not make an exacting analysis of all the factors in the British problem and of their relative nor does it attempt to do so. It only shows the Importance, has various trends which the development of the Problem tak­ en up to its present condition. of the thesis The original object was solely to analyse the effects of the devaluation on Britain’s III IV external trade. After partial study of this subject, it became apparent that the devaluation was too recent for such an analysis to be accurate. It would have been extremely difficult, if not impossible, to assess all the factors af­ fecting British trade following devaluation and to determine what degree of influence could be attributed to devaluation and what degree to extraneous factors. The original pro­ ject was, therefore, abandoned, and a more general discus­ sion of Britain’s balance-of-payments problem was under­ taken. Two chapters have, however, been devoted to sterling devaluation. Chapter 111 deals with the background of the action. Chapter IV shows the direction taken by British trade in the first year after devaluation; but it attempts merely to determine whether the objectives of the devaluation were achieved, rather than to make an accurate mathematical measurement of the effects of devaluation on British exports and imports. Aside from the problem of scope, there was the of selecting the source material. The writer has problem tried to be judicious in this respect. Where adequate and reliable summaries of the statistical data needed were used of the found, these were instead primary sources. In some instances, when certain data were not available, the writer had to make his own computations and estimates from V available figures. Due to the difference in the basis and method of computation in each certain minor dis- source, crepancies may be apparent in figures of the same type and for the same period. In all cases this writer has been primarily concerned with using those figures which best il­ lustrate a point or trend, rather than those which will as­ sure strict mathematical accuracy. The idea for this study originated out of class discussions on the subject of currency devaluation in some of Dr. Wendell C. Gordonf s courses. It took definite form in the course of personal conferences with Dr. Gordon. This writer is deeply grateful to Dr. Gordon for his assistance and guidance in the preparation of this thesis. His criticisms and suggestions were invaluable, and his words of approval and encouragement reassuring. The writer to Professor Edward E. the is also grateful Hale who read final draft of the thesis. Finally, the writer wishes to acknowledge aid re­ ceived from the British Information Services, an agency of the British Government with offices in New York. This agency supplied the latest trade and balance-of-payments figures, as well as other information on recent developments May 2, 1952 TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE I. BRITAIN'S FOREIGN TRADE PROBLEM 1 Britain’s Declining Export Trade 2 World War fls~ The Fr obletifrTntled. 20 ensif ... 11. THE BRITISH CRISIS 55 The Immediate Post-war Problem 57 Achlevfng An~Qverail Balance 5^ The Dollar Deficit 58 ffHe Crisis : Loss of Gold and Dollar'"Reserve s JO 111. DEVALUATION OF THE POUND STERLING 79 The Basic Causes of Devaluation 80 The Immediate Causes of Devaluation 101 Readjustment of~ForeTgn Currencies!* 107 IV. THE IMMEDIATE EFFECTS OF DEVALUATION 115 United Kingdom Merchandise Trade in the First Year After Devaluation 115 Improvement in the Balanceof^Payments. .159 .. Evaluation 146 V. THE 1951 CRISIS 152* VI. BRITAIN’S DILEMMA 165 182 BIBLIOGRAPHY * . . . ...... VI LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS PAGE CHAPTER I Chart 1. Volume of United Kingdom Trade 16 Chart 2. United Kingdom Terms of Trade Export Prices Divided by Im­ port Prices (1913 = 100) 16 CHAPTER II Chart 1. Industrial Production in the United Kingdom Quarterly Average 1946=100 49 Chart 2. Volume and Value of United Kingdom Exports of Manu­ factures (1958=100) 53 CHAPTER 111 Table 1. Value of United Kingdom Ex­ ports (including re-exports) to the United States and Canada, July 1948-June 1949 (in millions of pounds ster­ ling) 105 CHAPTER IV Chart 1. Value of United Kingdom Ex­ ports to and Imports from the United States in Pounds Sterling and the Wholesale Price Index of the United Kingdom, July 1949-Septem­ ber 1950 117 Chart 2. Value of United Kingdom Ex­ ports to and Imports from the United States in Dol­ lars and the Wholesale Price Index of the United Kingdom, July 1949-September 1950 .... 120 Chart 3» Value of United Kingdom Ex­ ports to and Imports from Canada in Pounds Sterling and the Wholesale Price Index of the United Kingdom, July 1949-September 1950 .... 124 VII CHAPTER IV , v (continued) PAGE Chart A. Value of United Kingdom Ex­ports to and Imports from Canada in Dollars and the Wholesale Price Index of the Chart 5* United Kingdom, July September 1950 Value of United Kingdom Ex­ports to and Imports from India in Pounds Sterling and the Wholesale Price In­ 125 Chart 6. dex of the United Kingdom, July 1949-September 1950 Value of United Kingdom Ex­ports to and Imports from 131 Pakistan in Pounds Sterling and the Wholesale Price In- Chart 7* dex of the United Kingdom, July 1950 .... Value of Total United King­dom Exports and Imports In Pounds Sterling and the Wholesale Price Index of .133 the United Kingdom, 1950 July 135 Chart 8. Terms of Trade of the United Kingdom, July 1950 (1947=100). . . 140 Chapter I BRITAIN'S FOREIGN TRADE PROBLEM It Is always difficult to determine where the roots of a problem lie; for, usually a problem is not appreciated In Its entire significance until it has reached a critical stage, and then the basic factors which underlie the trouble are obscured by the Immediate causes which precipitate the crisis. This appears to be the case with Britain's balance- The of-payments problem. crisis that Britain currently faces In her external payments has a grave world signif­ icance which Is not lost on the Informed and thinking mind. A great deal has been said and written about the British problem. It has been discussed by the leading statesmen and government officials of the English-speaking countries. It has been analyzed by economists the world over. Current the periodical literature abounds with material on subject. It Is a topic of study In academic circles. Yet, most of this discussion and study appears to be concerned with the Immediate background of the Problem. It seeks to explain Britain's difficulty In terms of relatively recent develop­ ments. Unfortunately, little has been said about the funda­ mental causes of the problem. Little has been written about the nature of the forces that operated over the long run to the generate problem. 1 Britain's balance-of-payments problem, although ag­ the Second World War and although it reached the gravated by critical stage in the post-war period, is of long standing. It is primarily a foreign trade problem, for it stems from a growing imbalance in Britain ! s foreign trade which can be traced back to the nineteenth century. The nature of Britain’s trade problem must be understood if the true mean­ ing of the balance-of-payments problem is to be appreciated. It is, therefore, the purpose of this chapter to analyse certain long-term trends in Britain's foreign trade which gave rise to the balance-of-payments problem and set the stage for its climax. Britain's Declining Export Trade Britain has been dependent to a marked extent on international trade. It is difficult for the average land of American, living in a virtual self-sufficiency, to understand the tremendously important role that foreign trade plays in the life of the British nation. The con- of a stoppage in the flow of trade to and from sequences the are all too obvious to merit detailed United Kingdom elaboration here. It is an accepted fact that in order to live Britain must import. She must import food to feed her 3 people and raw materials to supply her industries. But, in order to import, she must export her manufactured goods to obtain the foreign currencies with which to pay for the foodstuffs and raw materials that she needs. During the greater part of the nineteenth century, Britain had little difficulty in maintaining this flow of of imports and exports. Her far-flung empire provided most the foodstuffs and raw materials that were needed to feed a an growing population and to operate expanding productive establishment at home. British manufactured goods, as well as such vital Industrial materials as coal, pig iron, and steel, had no serious competition in world markets, and the flow of to foreign countries was maintained with exports relative ease. Britain was mistress of the seas, and her navy could, without serious difficulty, protect the empire and keep open the trade routes leading to and from the United Kingdom. These three factors, (l) a world-wide empire, and in the (2) a virtual monopoly in manufacturing produc­ tion of industrial materials, and (3) a strong navy assured to Britain a position of power and wealth never before en­ joyed by any other nation in history. It was by such means that a small ''nation of shopkeepers", living on an island which a fraction of the food and raw materials can produce only could extend its dominion over the globe without it needs, 4 danger of being effectively challenged by any foreign power and could champion free trade between nations without danger to of losing ground foreign competitors. Toward the end of the nineteenth and at the begin­ ning of the twentieth centuries this situation began to change. The rise of Germany on the Continent, the arrival of the United States as a world power, and the growing of strength Japan in Asia posed a challenge to Britain’s of world Material position leadership. progress had pro­ ceeded at a phenomenal rate in Germany during the last quarter of the nineteenth century, and that nation was rapid­ ly attaining political and economic predominance on the European continent. The sudden rise of the United States, following the Spanish-Amerlean War of 1898, to a world-power status gave her a leading role in the Western Hemisphere and an important position In the Western Pacific and China. In Asia, the "westernization" of Japan had begun to bear fr*uit, and that country was beginning to make a serious bid for in the Far East. ascendancy What was more Important, however, as concerns Britain’s was the rapid Industrlallzatlon of those three foreign trade, well as others like Buss la, and India. countries, as Canada, While the industrializing process was going on in these places, Britain profited from her exports of capital goods 5 to them, but as they began to produce goods for themselves, their purchases of British goods were reduced accordingly. Until 1913 this trend, although already noticeable, was still having only a negligible effect on British exports. Between 1913 and 1937, however, the volume of British ex­ ports to the industrialized and industrializing countries was reduced by one-half. Exports to three of these countries, India, Japan, and Russia, "actually fell by two-thir»ds." At the same time, exports to countries which remained predomi­ nantly primary producers "hardly fell at all."^ 1 MacDougall, G* D. A. Britain's Foreign Trade Problem”, Economic Journal, Vol. LVII, March P* 81. While the industrializing countries were thus cap­ turing their own domestic markets and pushing out British goods, an even more serious threat to Britain’s export trade was the growing competition which the products of Germany, the United States, and Japan were offering to British goods on the world market. This competition began at about the turn of the century, but up until the First World War its effects had not made themselves felt, mainly because of the rapid expansion of total world trade which enabled Britain p to expand her own trade up to the outbreak of the war. 2 Abrams, M. (ed.), Britain and Her Export Trade (London: Pilot Press, 1946X7 P* After 1913, however, such competition became increasingly serious. In the case of coal, for Instance, although Britain continued to produce about one-fifth of the total world production, her share in the volume of the world ! s coal exports fell from 55 percent in 1913 to 37 percent in 1938* In the same period Germany, despite her terri­ torial losses in 1918, Increased her share from 23 to 31 percent.'' Even more important than this decline in 5 Ibid., pp. 244-243. Britain f s relative share of world coal exports was the ab­ solute decline in British coal exports, as compared with and German coal exports. Between 1913 1938, while British exports (in millions of metric tons) were halved, German exports (in millions of metric tons) remained approximately li the same. Similar evidence is to be found concerning 4 The Economist, March 2j5, 1946, p. 461. of cotton goods. Between 1913 1937 the volume exports and f of world trade in cotton goods fell by 38 percent. Britain s 7 share in this declining total fell from 65 to 26 percent, while Japan’s share increased from practically nothing to 39 percent. In 1937-38 Japan's share was 50 percent greater than Britain's absolute decline was even greater 5 Abrams, op. clt., pp. 251 and 256. Between 1912 and 1938 British exports of cotton goods (in millions of square yards) fell by about 80 percent. During 6 Calculated from figures In Abrams, op. cit., p. 255* the same period Japanese exports increased substantially (no specific figures are readily available). Britain's exports of all manufactured articles also declined considerably after 1913* Between 1913 and 1936-38 the quantum of United of fell Kingdom (including Ireland) exports manufactures by 37*1 percent. At the same time, Germany's exports of manufactures fell by only 16 percent, while those of the United States increased by 54.8 percent and those of Japan by 371*6 The Impression given by the above figures League of Nations, Industrialization and Foreign Trade (1945), PP* 162-163. 8 Is that In the period between the two wars, British exports declined, not only as regards their share in total world ex ports but also absolutely. It is beyond the purpose of this study to analyse the various factors contributing to this loss of markets to foreign competition. Suffice it to point out that most British industries continued to use out-dated equipment and techniques after the First World War, while the new indus­ the ata trial nations, coming on scene later date, were able to adopt more modern equipment and techniques without suffering serious dislocations. As a result, British productivity decreased relative to foreign productivity, and Brltaln f s ability to produce and export was reduced relative to that of her competitors. While the industrialization of foreign countries (and especially the growing competition of Germany, the United States, and Japan) must be taken as the fundamental of the long-term decline in Britain's export trade, cause to the after two other factors contributing decline 1913 be considered. These were (l) ’’the growth of must also other trade barriers which limited the total tariffs and world trade In manufactures”, and (2) ”the over-valuation which reduced our share of that of sterling ® trade”. 8 MacDougall, loc. clt., p* 80. Tariffs and other trade restrictions underwent an un­ precedented growth In the Inter-war period. In continental Europe the general tariff level rose considerably above the pre-Vorld War I level. More Important for Its effect on British exports was the fact that "the tariff level on manufactured goods nearly doubled between 1913 and 1931*"^ 9 MacDougall, loc> clt., p. 85. In the United States, the Fordney-McCumber Tariff Act of 1922 rates provided for the highest In American tariff history up to that time, and the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 raised duties for some commodities 50 to 100 percent above the 1922 levels. The adoption of the latter Act was followed by higher tariffs In Canada, Cuba, Mexico, France, Italy, Spain, Australia, and New Zealand. Even Britain abandoned her traditional free-trade policy with the adoption of emer­ gency duties In 1931 and her first general tariff In February 10 1932. Tariff rates were also raised considerably In 10 League of Nations, Commercial Policy In the Inter war Period: International Proposals ar^NatlonalTolTcfes (Geneva, 19^2J, p. 52. Asiatic countries like India and Japan. One of the few ex­ ceptions to this general Increase In tariffs was Latin­ Also in wide in the inter-war period was usage 11 Commercial Policy in the Interwar> Period: Inter­national Proposals lonat^PoTicle p. s, bilateralism. Many countries facing balance-of-payments difficulties "restricted their imports from countries with which they had balances". "sum of all 'unfavourable' The the 'unfavourable' balances between pairs of countries represented one-quarter of international trade." Cutting off to that sum of "unfavourable" balances Imports equal 12 would have thus reduced total world trade by one-fourth. 12 MacDougall, loc. clt., p. 86. Other trade barriers, such as exchange controls, quotas, also gained wide-spread adoption, especially during etc., of multilateral trade broke down the 1930's when the system and the trading countries turned to commercial warfare. From the of the world economic crisis in 1929, beginning ever-increasing efforts were made to restrict imports by "the non-tariff measures. After 1931 such measures became instruments of commercial policy", and tar- most important -I^s iffs took secondary importance. Tariff levels, however. 13 Tariff Levels and the Economic Unity Lieprnann, H., of Europe, translated by H. Sterming (London: Se'drge “Allen* 40-41. & Unw'fn~£td., 1938), PP* 11 remained high throughout the 1930'5, despite numerous international attempts to bring about a general reduction or at least to do away with the worst features of the tariff situation. It is obvious that the growth of trade barriers in the inter-war period could result in only a general shrinkage of total world trade. More important, however, was the effect that such restrictions had on world trade in manufactures. Although between 1913 and 1937 the world's output of manufactures doubled, "international trade in manufactures failed to rise”. As a matter of fact, be­ 14 MacDougall, loc. clt., p. 85. tween 1913 and 1936-38* the quantum of world trade in manu­l^ factured articles fell by 7*9 percent. 15 Industrialization and Foreign Trade, p. 157• The second factor responsible for the decline in f after 1913 was the overvaluation of ster- Brttains exports ling In relation to other currencies. Between 1913 and 1922 Britain's exports of manufactured goods (in volume) "fell by some in relation to those of the United States, and this relative fall continued steadily during the rest of the 'twenties.” Although there was a sudden reversal of this trend In 1932, It continued its downward course after 1933­ The relative decline In Britain's exports between 1913 and 1930 may be attributed to the high prices of her manufactures. During the 1920's Britain was attempting to sell her manufac­ tures "at gold prices one-third higher than those of the United States In comparison with 1913”* The same Is true with respect to Germany. Between 1925 and 1931 British gold prices were considerably higher than German gold prices In comparison with 1913, and Britain's exports of manufactures to those of (in volume) fell steadily in relation Germany. This Inverse relationship between the volume and gold price of Britain's exports Is also apparent when compared with the next exports of Japan and France, Britain's largest competi­ tors In the inter-war period. The continuing decline In Britain's share of the world market for manufactures was temporarily checked by the depreciation of sterling In 1931, a which for* a time made British goods cheaper than measure those of her competitors. The fall In Britain's export prices in relation to those of the United States, Germany, rise in the volume of and France resulted In a sharp relative of manufactures. The same, however, was British exports for It must not true with respect to Japan, be remembered at about the that Japan depreciated her currency same time extent than Britain. At and to a much greater any rate. 13 following the depreciation in 1931, Britain's "share in the total quantity (not value) of world exports of manufactures" that increased by one-third and remained at approximately level for four years. The rise in British exports of manu­ factures relative to those of the United States and Germany was not maintained as long. When the United States depre­ ciated the dollar in 1933 and Britain's export prices rose again relative to those of the United States, British ex­ ports of manufactures fell steadily in relation to those of the United States up to the outbreak of the Second World War, After when British export prices relative to German export prices began to rise, Britain's exports of manufactures, in relation to those of Germany, fell off again. The rise in British exports relative to French ex­ ports following the depreciation in 1931 continued steadily until 1936. In that year, however, France devalued the franc, and Britain's relative exports again fell sharply. It has been noted that there was no increase in already Britain's of manufactures relative to those of exports Japan as a result of sterling depreciation. The steady de­ cline which had preceded the depreciation continued uninter­ the rupted during most of the 1930*5. In brief, favorable trend shown by Britain's exports of manufactures following in As the depreciation of sterling 1931 was short-lived. 14 other countries depreciated their currencies, the exchange value of sterling rose, and Britain’s quantitative share of the world's exports of manufactures fell off again. 16 MacDougall, loc. clt., pp. 103-107. Britain's share was a declining share in a declining world trade in manufactures. It is thus that the obvious growing competition of foreign countries, the growth of other tariffs and trade barriers in the inter-war period, and the overvaluation of sterling in relation to foreign currencies could only have a disastrous effect on Britain! s export trade in the long run. the sixty or before the First During seventy years World War, the volume of United Kingdom exports and the volume of United Kingdom imports' both rose steadily and more or less in line with each Between 1913 and 1938, 17 Ibid., pp. 78-79. the volume fell steadily, while the however, of exports volume of imports continued to rise (see Chart l). If both taken as 100 in 1913, the volume of exports in the five are years before the Second World War averaged 65, while that of 15 Imports averaged 125 Thus, "the volume of exports, relatlve­• ly to that of imports, had been halved." ° 18 The Economist, August J>o, p. 351* This growing imbalance in British foreign trade in the period between the two wars gave rise to Britain’s balance How to balance her of-payments problem. did Britain manage in the face of between external payments an ever-widening gap her exports and imports? Or rather, how did Britain manage for volume of while the volume to pay an increasing imports of her exports was declining? There are three possible ex- state of affairs. planations for this after on First, during the generation 1913, Britain, the whole, enjoyed increasingly advantageous terms of trade means that a unit Chart 2). This simply representative (see of British exports could be exchanged for an increasing volume of While this was not true during the First World imports. in the 1920's "(except in the boom years at the end of War, the terms of trade index stood at 120 (1913=100) the decade)" and in the early 1930’s it rose 140 or higher, to or higher, "in 1938 it stood at IjQ .The reason for Britain’s 19 Ibid. Chart 1. Volume of United Kingdom Trade Chart 2. United Kingdom Terras of Trade Exnort Prices Divided by Import Prices (1913=100) 17 Increasingly favorable terms of trade of the was, course, high prices of her exports relative to the prices of her imports. (The high prices of British manufactures relative to the of prices foreign manufactures was pointed out above in the discussion of the overvaluation of sterling). While of British the prices imports were no higher in 1938 than in 1913, the prices of British exports rose by about two­20 fifths. 20 MacDougall, loc* clt., p. 79. Secondly, Britain's earnings from "invisible" ex­ ports were for a long time more than enough to make up the deficit in "visible" trade. The most important of these invisible items was shipping. In 1913 receipts for shipping services were sufficient to pay for 71 percent of Britain's visible trade deficit. Although this percentage fell in the inter-war in services steadily period, 1938 shipping were still sufficient to cover 26 percent of the visible trade deficit. 21 With the total earnings from visible and 21 Abrams, op, clt., pp. 211 and 229. invisible trade, Britain was able to finance the growing volume of her for Imports many years. In 1913 total visible and Invisible exports not only paid for total Im­ ports, but exceeded them by about 30 percent. Between 1923 and 1929 the favorable margin was about 7 percent. Be­ tween 1950 and 1937* however, visible and Invisible exports and paid for only 97 percent of Imports, In 1938 for only 22 92 percent. 22 MacDougall, loc. clt., pp. 79-80. This leads to the third explanation. To pay for the excess of total Imports over total visible and Invisible ex­ ports, Britain had to draw on her overseas capital, 1.e., she had to sell or repatriate some of her foreign Investments. In 1938 the overall deficit In Britain's balance of payments amounted to 70 million pounds sterling, or "less than 2 per­ cent of the total overseas capital of the country." J The Economist, August 23* p. 310* Although this represents a small portion of total capital that Britain could not continue assets, it is apparent to live her overseas without serious indefinitely on capital as creditor consequences for her position the world's leading nation. The events of World War II were soon to prove this point with forceful clarity. 19 To summarize what has been said so far: Certain long-term trends indicate a steady decline in Britain's ex­ port trade, especially after 1915. The fundamental cause of this decline was the industrialization of foreign countries, and particularly the growing competition of Germany, the United States, and Japan. But two other causes were also responsible for Britain's falling exports after 1913: (1) "the growth of tariffs and other trade barriers which limited the total world trade in manufac­ tures”, and (2) "the over-valuation of sterling which re­ duced our share of that trade”. The resulting loss of exports, coupled with an increasing volume of im­ ports, gave rise to Britain's balance-of-payments difficul­ ty. Despite the adverse trade balance, certain factors helped Britain to balance her international accounts: (1) favorable terms of trade, (2) earnings from invisible and sale exports, especially shipping, (3) or repatriation of overseas capital. Although the depreciation of sterling in 1931 provided some relief for Britain's declining export trade, it proved to be only a temporary remedy because of the wave of competitive depreciations that followed. After trade deficit continued its about 1935 the growing pre-1931 trend. 20 World War II: The Problem Intensified The outbreak of the war in 1939 posed new and more serious problems for Britain, not the least of which was the necessity of adapting her entire economy to the require­ ments of total war. Regardless of Immediate and future all available resources had to be devoted consequences, primarily to the production of military goods for the suc­ cessful prosecution of the war. Industries, which In peace­ time had produced civilian goods for domestic consumption and for sale abroad, had to be converted to the production of guns, tanks, planes, and other military equipment; work­ ers who had been employed In the export Industries, had to be shifted to war Industries; and raw materials which had been used In making manufactured articles for export, had to be used to the Instruments of war. produce But, aside from this drastic change In the condi­ other factors tions of supply of exportable goods, also contributed to the contraction of Britain’s export trade the war. One of the first effects of the war was to during cut or at least to weaken many of the trade links that tied to overseas Britain to the European continent, countries, and to her empire. The conquest of Europe by Hitler’s markets legions closed most of the European to British Germany’s counter-blockade of the United Kingdom goods. and her vigorous submarine warfare against British ship­ ping seriously hampered British trade by Isolating the United Kingdom from many of Its overseas and empire markets and by reducing the carrying capacity of Brltalnf s merchant, fleet. Many of Britain's former customers were either forced to Industrialize In order to produce their own 24 manufactures or to replace British goods with those from 24 Industrialization was stimulated by the war in countries such as Canada, Australia, India, and Brazil (MacDougall, loc. clt., p. 83). other countries that could still export, the United e.g., 25 States. As the war progressed and Hitler's air blitz 25 Abrams, op. clt., p. 18; and Dacey, W. M. "British Reconversion and Trade", Forelgn Affairs, Vol. 23, January 1945, P. 253. struck at Britain's centers of production, British industries suffered considerable physical damage which cut down their and reduced even further the productive capacity proportion available for export. of their output The result of these developments was a drastic re­ duction In Britain's exports. By 1943 merchandise exports (excluding munitions) had fallen to 29 percent of their 22 volume, a drop of 71 percent in five years. Although there was a marked recovery by 1945, exports in that year were only at 45 percent of the 1938 level. The value of merchandise exports (excluding munitions) fell from 471 million pounds in 1938 to 233 million pounds in 1943, and then rose to 393 million pounds in 1945* 1943 i.e., by the value of exports had fallen to 49-5 percent of their 1938 value and then risen to 83.4 percent in 1945 Thus, al­ 26 Britain and World Trade (London: PEP, 1947)* P* 64. The percentages indicating the changes in the value of this writer. exports were computed by in both volume though exports picked up and value after 1943, the first four years of the war saw a sharp decline, with regard to volume. especially On the side of imports, the picture was similar in so far as volume was concerned (an important difference be- as their value will be tween exports and imports regards chief of the in the pointed out below). The cause drop to cut volume of imports was, of course, Germany's campaign Britain's life-line by means of a relentless submarine attack against British and Allied shipping. The resulting meant that all un­ scarcity of shipping space necessarily essential imports had to be ruthlessly cut, and that 23 priority had to be given to goods and materials vital to the war effort. Where possible. Imports were replaced by domestic This products. was especially true In the case of food. By 1941 retained Imports of food, drink, and tobacco had been reduced of to 72 percent their pre-war volume. An Improvement In 1942 and 1943 to 73 and 78 percent respectively, was not maintained In 1944, when such to of Imports fell again 75 percent the 1938 1eve1. 27 27 The Economist, August 11, 1945, p. 199 and table on 201. p. But, while food Imports declined, Britain’s war-time domestic output increased "by more than 70$ in terms of calories and of protein, and by 120$ in units of shipping if 28 space In an effort to save carrying space and at the . 28 MacDougall, loc. clt., p. 74. same time to pack as large a volume of essential goods Into of available shipping, Imports bulky commodities, such as feeding-stuffs, timber, Iron ore and scrap, and wood-pulp, were drastically cut, and, as far as possible, replaced by home products. In some cases, seml-flnlshed and finished goods were substituted for raw materials, e.g., seml-flnlshed 24 steel was substituted for iron and aluminum was ore, substituted for bauxite. were in Certain foods Imported dehydrated or concentrated form so as to reduce bulk and we ight 29 The Economist, August 11, 1945> P* 199* Like food, imports of raw materials and manufactures also had to be curtailed. By 1945 retained imports of raw materials and articles mainly unmanufactured had fallen to of their 1958 volume. There was a slight increase 59 percent to 61 percent in 1944. The explanation lies partly in in- especially of iron ore and creased domestic production, in the substitution (mentioned above) timber, and partly of semi-finished materials for primary products. Imports of finished manufactures were high relative to Imports of still remained below the pre-war raw materials, but they in 1944, when they stood at 105 percent level, except of "50 the 1958 volume. 30 and table on 201. Ibid., p. 199 p. result for total Imports was a reduc- The overall a less drastic reduction than tion In their volume, albeit In 1942 the volume of retained In the case of exports. imports (excluding munitions) fell to 70 percent of the 1938 volume, in 1944 it rose to 80 percent, and in 1945 it fell again to 63 percent. With regard to the value of Imports, the situation was altogether different. The value of re­ tained imports (excluding munitions) increased from 858 million pounds in 1938 to 1,291 million pounds in 1944 and then fell slightly to 1,051 million pounds in 1945, i.e., the of by 1944 value imports had risen to 150 percent of their 1938 value and then fallen to 122 percent in 1945.^ 31 Britain and World Trade, p. 64. The percentages indicating tHe changes In tlie value of Imports were com­puted by this writer. Throughout the war, then, while the money value of exports remained well below the 1938 level, the money value of imports exceeded the 1938 level by a considerable amount.* *AII the above figures on the volume and value of merchandise exports and Imports exclude munitions. A large share of lend-lease trade is, therefore, left out of the totals. Imports and exports of lend-lease raw materials and agricultural products, however, are included. During the the United Kingdom received $13,498.7 million In war, lend-lease goods from the United States. Of this total, munitions made up $6,783.0 million (The Economist, Septem­ber 1943, 355). This figure is not included in the 8, p. total value of Britain's imports. Reverse lend-lease, i.e., lend-lease goods exported by the United Kingdom to the United States, amounted to $3,796.9 million. Of this sum, muni­tions made up $976.7 million (Ibid.). This figure is not included in the total value of Britain's exports. If the and exports of munitions were value of Imports included, total value of Britain's the disparity between the imports and exports would obviously greater. be 26 This substantial increase in the value of imports, while their volume was decreasing, may be explained by the steady rise in import prices the during war. In terms of 1938 prices, the average price of Imports showed an in­ crease of 91 percent by 1944. At the same time, the aver­ age price of exports increased by 78 percent. This faster rise in the average price of imports was due partly, it should be to the fall in the of noted, value sterling in 1939, and to the partly fact that exports were priced f.0.b., while imports were priced c.i.f. The high cost of trans­ portation and insurance was thus included in the import prices, but not in the export prices. Transport costs during the war increased much more rapidly than the aver­ age price of exports.^2 32 The Economist, August 11, 1943, p. 200 and table on 201.“" p. The effect of a rise in the of money value Imports fall in the value and, simultaneously, a money of exports on Britain’s balance of payments is at once obvious. It simply meant that the pre-war trade deficit was increasing-^ 33 During the three years, 1936-38, the trade def­icit averaged 3°9 million pounds annually. In 1945 the deficit amounted to 658 million pounds (Calculated figures in Britain and World Trade, pp. 54 64). and 27 and that Britain’s problem was becoming increasingly dif­ ficult. The difficulty appears even more serious when it is noted that Britain suffered substantial losses in her invisible exports during the war. It should be remembered that before the war the greater portion of the visible trade deficit was covered by earnings from invisible exports. In the three years, 1956-58, invisible receipts averaged a net total of 545 million pounds a year. This figure was suf­ ficient to pay for about 89 percent of the average trade 54 The greatest war-time loss in Britain’s invisible 54 Calculated from figures in Britain and World Trade, p. 54. in income from overseas capital investments. was earnings such income Over the three-year period, 1956-38, averaged a net sum of 205 million pounds annually. This figure alone of trade was sufficient to cover 52 percent the average deficit.3s 1945 net receipts of dividends and interest By 55 Ibid. had fallen to million British investments 97 on overseas This amount covered only about 15 percent of pounds 56 Cmd. 6707, Statistical Material Presented During Station- the Washington Negotiations -CLondonTHis Majesty*s officer December 1945T7 P* ery of the trade deficit. There are no figures available on earnings of other British Invisibles during the war. Prom figures on war-time shipping losses. It can be assumed that shipping Income, which averaged a net sum of 105 mtl­ -37 lion pounds a year In 1936-38, declined, though perhaps 37 Britain and World Trade, p. s^* not In the same proportion as Income from overseas invest­ ments. At the beginning of the war, the United Kingdom had a merchant fleet of 22.1 million deadweight tons. Dur­ ing the war total losses amounted to 18 million tons, but million tons) was made a good part of this loss (15.3 good With 3»5 by new building, captures, and acquisitions. million tons In acquired vessels being returnable, Britain’s June amounted to 15.9 million merchant fleet on 30, 38 tons, or less than three-quarters of the pre-war tonnage.^ 38 8. Cmd. 6707> P* that British war-time were It must be remembered imports c.i.f. All earnings of British vessels carrying priced therefore, be cancelled imports to the United Kingdom would, out their inclusion in the c.i.f. value of imports, and by would be net shipping income on the balance of payments substantially less than the actual total of shipping earn­ ings. This would make the war-time loss of earnings seem small on the balance of payments. Net shipping Income In the first post-war year, amounted to 29 million 39 pounds, a sharp drop from the 1936-38 If this average. 39 Calculated from figures in Cmd. 8065, United Kingdom Balance of Payments 1946 to 1950 (London:' His J Majesty's Stationery Office, October I95O), p. 7. figure were calculated at 1938 prices, it would be even smaller, for freight rates Increased considerably during the war, and by were about double level. their pre-war Without data on total invisible earnings during the It war. Is Impossible to determine what part they played In meeting Britain's adverse balance of visible trade. In 1946 total invisible receipts amounted to 438 million pounds; however, invisible payments In 1946 totalled 610 million pounds (of which government overseas expenditures made up 363 mllllbn alone pounds), so that actually there was a deficit of 172 mll­ -40 In Britain’s Invisible trade. Instead lion pounds Thus, 40 Ibid. of financing the greater part of the visible trade deficit and relieving the balance-of-payments difficulty (as In the invisible trade added pre-war years), Britain's even more to the overall balance-of-payments deficit In 1946. Whereas, In the three years, 1936-33, Brttaln‘s balance-of-payments deficit averaged 44 million pounds ln 1946 the 41 Britain and World Trade, p. 54. lipdeficit amounted to 348 million pounds. The peak in the 42 Cmd. 8065, p. 7. deficit, however, was reached during the war years, when it 4"5 averaged about 700 million pounds annually. 43 Britain and World Trade, p. 55­ In order to the large war-time deficits, cover Britain had to use four methods of finance. First, the Government was forced to draw on reserves of gold and dollars. These reserves fell from a total United States millionof 605 million pounds on August 31, 1939 to 74 pounds on December 31, 1940. By June 30, 1943 they had to million pounds, but were still 152 been restored 453 44 million pounds below the 1939 Secondly, level. the 44 Cmd. 6707, P* 11­ of liquidation overseas capital, which had been employed to a small extent to meet the pre-war deficit, was ac­ celerated. In 1938 the nominal value of United Kingdom overseas Investments was estimated at 3,725 million 45 the pounds. During war the Government sold or repatriated 45 Britain and World Trade, p. 57. /T 1,118 million pounds of this total, representing a loss 46 Cmd. 6707, p. 9* of 50 percent of Britalnf s capital Investments abroad. Thirdly, Britain accumulated large external liabilities the war. At the end of 1959 Britain*s during August debts abroad totalled 4j6 million pounds. By the end of June 1943 they had increased by 2,879 million pounds to far the 3,355 million pounds. Of this amount, by larger million pounds, consisted portion, 3,052 of sterling and the remainder, 303 million pounds, consisted 47 of overseas loans. 1 Fourthly, net imports of lend-lease balances, 47 Ibid., p. 10. goods other than munitions were covered by the lend-lease aid urogram which was adopted by the United States in March 1941. 32 Britain’s reserves of gold and United States dol­lars, although substantially depleted In the first two years of the had war, to been replenished a considerable extent by 1943* Their loss over the whole war period was, therefore, not extremely serious. The depletion of over-assets, while much seas greater during the war than In the pre-war period, also as serious as might was not appear at first. A loss of 30 percent In capital Investments abroad Indicates that a large portion of Britain’s overseas wealth remained Intact. This view tends to be substantiated the fact by that in 1945 gross receipts from foreign In­ vestments still amounted to 170 million pounds as compared with little more than 200 million pounds before the war.^ 48 MacDougall, loc. clt., p. 70. The realization of overseas assets, however, played a vital role In the Initial phase of Britain’s war effort. These assets enabled Britain to pay for essential Imports, for military operations abroad, and for "cash and carry" ship­ments of munitions and other equipment from the United States while that country was still at peace and before liQ lend-lease aid went into effect. The greatest cause for 40. Abrams, op. clt., p. 33 concern, however, was the accumulation of large external liabilities. These liabilities, most of which were in the form of sterling balances held in London banks, provided the principal means of financing Britain's overseas military expend­ itures and purchases of war goods. Without them, Britain could not have obtained the means necessary waging total war. The greatest share of the sterling balances was accumulated by countries in the sterling area, especially India and While these debts no Egypt. incurring presented great difficulty, their repayment, which would require ex­ ports in excess of those needed to pay for current imports, was to pose a serious problem for Britain in the post-war period. The increase of 2,879 million pounds in Britain's external debt between September 1959 and June represents an extremely heavy burden that the country could ill afford to incur. In the words of Lord Keynes, Britain "fought this war on the principle of unlimited liability and with more reckless disregard of economic consequences than it 50 others more fortunately placed. 50 In Britain and World Trade, p. 55• quoted from the realization of overseas While proceeds and the use of gold and dollar reserves assets capital 34 contributed considerably to meet the war-time balance- of-payments deficit, it is obvious that the greatest part of the deficit was covered by the accumulation of external liabilities. The sum of these three, i.e., the total dis- to million investment of the United Kingdom, amounted 4,198 pounds for the period between September 1959 and June 1945* This sum represents the loss of overseas wealth suffered by Britain in order to finance her war Such a loss 51 Cmd. 6707, P* 12. could only portend disaster for Britain’s international capital position after the war. Chapter II THE BRITISH CRISIS It has been shown in the second part of the first chapter how the Second World War intensified balance- of-payments difficulty, and how, in order to meet the grow­ ing deficit, the United Kingdom had to resort to external disinvestment on an extremely large scale. Such extensive disinvestment ended, for all practical purposes, Britain's traditional creditor-nation status. She emerged from the war with a large foreign debt, with net income her over­ seas investments substantially reduced, and with her reserves of gold and foreign exchange considerably diminished. All this should not, however, be taken to mean that Britain had become a net debtor. As noted in the first chapter, a large portion of her overseas investments remained intact, and at the end of the war she was still earning a substantial gross income on her investments. But, though still a net creditor, Britain was not financially strong. In addition to the investments liquidated during the war, which repre­ overseas sented about 30 percent of her total assets, be­ tween 10 and 15 percent were "temporarily or permanently lost as a result of enemy action," and about 20 percent had "little more than speculative value." Thus, actually 35 36 "not more than 35 to 40 of percent prewar oversea Invest­ ments will return an Income during the transitional period." More important was the fact that by the end of the war Britain f s net Income from investments abroad had been drastically reduced. As noted in the preceding chapter, such income amounted to only 97 million pounds in 1945. This fact overshadowed any optimism arising from the thought that Britain was still a net creditor, for "it is the size of the net income from overseas which will be im­ portant in determining the external postwar financial posi­ tion of the nation."^ 1 Heatherington, D. F. "British Postwar Balance of International Payments", Foreign Commerce Weekly, Vol. XX, August 25, P-3* Because of the immediate problems it raised, the most disastrous blow to Britainf s external financial posi­ tion was the accumulation of the large overseas debt dur­ ing the war. To free all the sterling balances immediately after the war would have required a sum greater than the for the total of Britain f s merchandise exports seven years the war, and the use of all gold and dollar re- preceding serves would have covered only one-fifth of the total claims 2 outstanding. 2 Ibid. 37 The Immediate Post-war Problem For purposes of this study, the chief importance of the war-time change in Britain's international capital status lies in its influence on the post-war balance of payments. As pointed out in the preceding chapter, the loss of earn- other ings from shipping, foreign investments, and invisibles during the war, rendered invisible trade inadequate to meet Britain's traditional visible trade deficit. Instead, net invisible losses were adding to the overall balance-of-payments deficit. At the end of the war Britain faced an even greater deficit. The expansion of exports would have to await the reconversion of war industries to peace-time production. During this transitional period, however, large imports of capital goods, raw materials, and food would be needed to reconstruct war-torn industries and to supply domestic de­ mand to a degree commensurate with a reasonable standard of living. Britain's Immediate post-war problem, then, was that of finding the means to finance an Increased balance- deficit in a transitional period when receipts of-payments from British exports would be inadequate to pay for the necessary for the rapid reconversion and reconstruc imports tion of production facilities. The cessation of lend-lease aid from the United States immediately after the war elimi­ nated that medium as a possible solution of the problem. The further reduction of gold and dollar reserves and the further liquidation of overseas assets would not only ruin Britain financially, but would be insufficient to cover the impending deficit. Except for limited use, both these media had to be ruled out. One other alternative remained: an Increase In the the foreign debt. The magnitude of existing sterling balances, however, made the Government wary of Increasing the country f s external liabilities, or at least anxious to keep a further Increase to a minimum. The problem was ful­ ly recognized even before the end of the war by the Chancel­ lor of the Exchequer, Sir John Anderson, In his Budget speech of April 24, 1945: For the first three years after the war I fore­see a very heavy deficit on current account In the balance of payments. In other words, for the Imports which will be absolutely essential to feed our people, and to provide raw materials for Industry, we shall have to incur further Indebtedness. How large that Indebtedness Is and how long It lasts, depends on two questions to which In large part we ourselves can provide The first is the sense of the answers. urgency with which we treat the expansion of our export even if that means waiting a little trade, longer before we satisfy our personal wants in fu11.... The second question is how far we shall be willing to enforce a strict economy In ex- What we must avoid ternal cash expenditure.... is commitments which might be beyond unnecessary our continuing strength, and we must closely limit external expenditure which does not pro­duce a fairly quick return.^ 3 Quoted in Heatherington, loc. clt., p. 45. The only possible solution, however undesirable, seemed to be further Indebtedness abroad In the form of long-term credits. With many misgivings and despite much criticism at home, the British Government, therefore, decided to enter into a financial agreement with the United States which would enable Britain to adjust her balance of payments other than through a drastic reduction of imports. The actual agreement, concluded on December 6, 1945 and known not as the Anglo-American Financial Agreement, reflected Britain's need for immediate financial assistance to only make this adjustment, but also "the American desire that any such adjustment be made only within the framework of a multilateral Aside from this desire to restore 4 Polk, J. and Patterson, Q. "The British Loan”, Foreign Affairs, Vol. 24, April 1946, p. 432. multilateral trade, the United States was also anxious to end all outright "gifts” and to substitute for a "giv- American ing” system a "lending" system. Hence, the ne­ insisted that any further assistance to Britain gotiators in the form of a loan rather than a continuation should be of lend-lease aid. A section of the Agreement provided for full settlement of lend-lease. The United Kingdom 40 agreed to pay the United States $650 million, and the slate was thus wiped clean. c;J Under the principal terms of the 5 Polk and Patterson, loc. clt., p. 433. Agreement, the United States agreed to extend a line of credit of $3,750 million to the United Kingdom. The purpose of this credit, as stated In section 3 of the Agreement, was to facilitate purchases by the United Kingdom of goods and services in the United States, to assist the United Kingdom to meet transitional post-war deficits In Its current balance of to payments, help the United Kingdom to maintain adequate re­serves of gold and dollars and to assist the Government of the United Kingdom to assume the obligations of multilateral trade, as defined In this and other agreements.^ 6 Cmd. G7OB, Financial Agreement Between the Govern ments of the United States and the United Kingdom (London: His Majesty rs’"stationery offfee, December "154*5P» 2. The loan was to be Interest-free until December 31, 1951, at which time repayment would begin, and be made In 50 annual installments, at an interest rate of 2 percent per annumJ 7 Ibid. On March 6, 1946 a similar agreement was concluded with Canada whereby the United Kingdom was to receive a credit of and $1,250 million for the same purpose on the same o terms of repayment as the American loan/ These credits. 8 Cmd, 6904, Financial Agreement and Agreement on the Settlement of War Claims Betveen the Governments of" the United' s Kingdom ~and^Canada~[London: Hi’s Majesty T Stationery Office, September 194b), p. 3. then, were meant to enable the United Kingdom to obtain the imports needed for the quick reconversion of its war-time economy without the immediate pressure of balancing its international payments* Despite the absence of this immediate pressure, the British Government took great care not to squander the American and Canadian loans in a mad dash for imports. Quantitative import restrictions were imposed and only those Imports essential to the reconversion effort were permitted to enter. Such a policy necessitated the adop­ tion of a of *austerity” at home, a measure which program entailed great sacrifices for the British consumer. The result was only a moderate rise in the volume of imports. In 1945 the volume of retained Imports of the United 62 the volume. it had Kingdom was percent of 1938 By 1948 This risen slightly to 8l percent of 1938. represents an increase of 30 percent in the three years, 1946-48.^ 9 The Scope Yearbook of Industry, Trade and Finance 1951 (London: Scope Books Ltd.V 1951), P» 554 * The rise in the value of retained imports, however, was substantial. From 1,052.7 million pounds in 1945, it rose to 2,015.0 million pounds in 1948. In 1945 it was 122 per­ cent of the 1958 value. By 1948 it had risen to 235 per­ cent. This represents an increase of 92 percent in the years, 1946-48. Thus, while the Government was talcing 10 The Board of Trade Journal, February 15, 1947, The p. 277, and Pebruary 5, p. percentages • indicating the rise in the value of retained imports were computed by this writer. steps to limit the volume of imports to those goods which were essential to the reconversion program, their value nearly doubled in the three post-war years, 1946-48. This condition may be explained in part by the trend in the values of imports. Index numbers of the average average values of total imports show an increase from 193 percent an of the 1958 level in 1945 to 289 percent in 1948, or 46 in 1946-48.8ut index numbers of increase of percent Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 87, 1938-1949 His Majesty »s Stationery office"/ 1951T, P-287. (London: accurate values cannot be relied upon as an Indlca average trends. Their chief worth Is In reducing tion of price values to the price levels of the base year (in current 43 this case 1938). They can only be used as a rough guide to price movements from year to year, "since they are in­ fluenced by changes in the composition of trade as well as by price ¦1 pmovements.” The indices of Import prices for the 12 Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 87, 1938-1949, footnote to table on“p7 287• For -auTl explanatfon ofhe meaning of average value Indices and the difference between them and price indices of imports and exports, see The Board of Trade Journal, April 13, 1946, 420. p. early post-war years show a continuation of the steady war­ time increase in British import prices. In December 1945 of total were of the 1938 prices imports 195 percent 1 l^ average. By December 1948 they had risen to 297 percent. 15 Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 85, 1937-1947, p. 248. 14 The Board of Trade Journal, February 5, 1949, p. 239. This indicates an increase of 52 percent in 1946-48. The offers 18 altogether satisfactory, explanation for the substantial rise in import prices a more acceptable, though not 15 The import price indices indicate the in changes the aggregate a representative quantity of Imports. value of This quantity is multiplied by the unit value computed from Trade Accounts of the Board of Trade for the the monthly 44 month In question and for* the base year* 1938. In comput­ ing the unit value, some of the less important headings of United Kingdom imports are aggregated with one or* of the principal headings listed in the Trade Accounts to obtain a representative collection of headings. Thus, “the of movement unit values for such an aggregation of is of headings not necessarily a measure the true price movement of any one of the items included, if the make-up within the aggregated heading is changing significantly. (The Journal, April 13, p. also Board of Trade gTves a~de tailed account~o7 the method of compiling the price indices.) increase in the value of (despite only a slight Increase in the volume of) retained imports. While the value of British Imports was rising fast in the immediate post-war strenuous efforts were years, being made by the Government to expand exports as quickly The Financial with the United as possible. Agreement States could not be expected to postpone indefinitely the immediate need for exports to pay for imports, and in order to balance her current accounts, it was Imperative that Britain raise the volume of her exports substantially above Before the conclusion of the Financial the 1938 level. io was estimated that British exports would have Agreement, to be increased by 50 percent above the 1938 volume in order to just for the pre-war volume of imports. The pay likelihood of imports in excess of the pre-war volume dur­ ing the transitional period and after, as well as the financial burdens incurred in the and the Agreement need for overseas expenditures to build up an enlarged volume of new trade, raised the target to 75 percent above the 1958 volume. The greater portion of the increase was 16 Cmd. 6707, Statistical Material Presented During the Washington Negotiatlons~TLondon: His Majestyl!* Statfonery Offfee7 cember p. 5* to be concentrated on manufactures, and In order for total exports to rise by 75 percent above 1938, It was estimated that the volume of exports of manufactures would have to l^ rise by a little over 100 percent. 17 The Economist, December 15, P* 850. such a be Obviously, large target could only achieved by a quick resumption of full-scale industrial production, and especially by a substantial expansion of Britain's export industries. While the export drive was left primarily to the initiative of private businessmen, the Government played an important role in assisting and regu­ for lating the program. Exporters were given priority the end manpower and materials (although of positive labor controls made a priority for manpower quite ineffective, of the low levels in some of especially because wage the 46 principal export industries). Industries were encouraged to form or reform export groups to assist in meeting export quotas. The Government's staffs for assisting and advising traders at home and abroad were strengthened. And shipping 18 was allocated as rapidly as possible. The Immediate 18 The Economist, November 3, P* 621. problem for Britain, however, was not one of marketing, but of This that of secur­ production. raised another problem, an share of total production to meet export ing adequate demands. It was natural that with a high level of domestic demand, British manufacturers should consider production for sale at home more attractive than production for sale abroad. Thus, in order to make adequate facilities avail­ able for export production, the Government had to place IQ on domestic demand. v This deferment of restrictions Britain and World Trade (London; PEP, 194?)> p. 11l from the satisfaction of home needs to the satis­ production faction of export demands intensified the "austerity" im­ to "aus­ restrictions. Needless say, posed by the import to be extremely unpopular with the British terity" proved 47 people, but it is difficult to suggest an alternative policy that might have offered better prospects of suc­ cess . Despite the efforts of the British Government to increase production as rapidly as possible, total indus­ trial production of the United Kingdom Increased only slightly over pre-war production. In 1946 industrial production in general was 96 percent of 1938. By 1948 it was 116 percent, an increase of only 16 percent over the pre-war level in the first three post-war years. Compared 20 Computed from figures in International Financial Statistics, Vol. 111, January 1950,’~pTT5C37 with production in 1946, the increase in 1947-48 was slight­ ly greater* In 1947 the monthly average of total industrial was of the production 108 percent 1946 monthly average. By 1948 it had increased sharply to 121 percent, a rise of 21 percent over 1946 in two years. The quarterly index shows increase. In the fourth quarter of 1947 a still greater total production was 119 percent of the 1946 quarterly In the of 1948 it was 126 average. fourth quarter percent (see Chart l). Thus, although the increase in total pro­ duction during 1946-48 appears slight when compared with the 1938 level, it was considerable during 1947-48 when compared with the 1946 level. Production in the manufactur­ ing industries, the key to export expansion, also increased considerably (almost pari passu with total production) when compared with 1946. In 194? the monthly average of pro­ duction in manufacturing industries was 109 percent of the 1946 average. By 1948 it had risen to 125 percent. The quarterly index shows that in the fourth quarter of 1947 production in manufacturing industries was 120 percent of the 1946 quarterly average. In the fourth quarter of 1948 it PI was 128 percent (see Chart 1). 21 Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 87, 1958-1949, pp. 128-123: The export drive conducted by the British Govern­ ment produced remarkable results in an amazingly short time. The volume of United Kingdom exports rose from 46 percent of the 19j58 volume in 1945 to 99 percent in 1946. This of in one represents an increase 115 percent year. By had risen to 156 percent of the 1958 volume, 1948 exports which indicates an increase of 195 percent in the three 22 1946-48. Although the 1948 volume was still years, 22 The Scope Yearbook of Industry, Trade and Finance 1951, P. 5W­ the of considerably below export target 75 percent above Chart 1. Industrial Production in the United Kingdom Quarterly Average 1946= 100 50 increase 1938, the rapid in the first three post-war years as an must be regarded admirable achievement. The value of United Kingdom exports increased tremendously in the same three-year period. From 399 million pounds in 1945, it rose to 1,583 million pounds in 1948. In 1945 it was 84.7 percent of the 1938 value. 1948 it had risen By to an 338.1 percent. This represents increase of 297 percent in the three years, 1946-48. As in the case of imports, 25 The Scope Yearbook of Industry, Trade and Finance 1931. p. SST. rise in the value of the exports may be explained in part the rise in the average values of exports. In 1945 by these average values stood at 185 percent of 1938. By 1948 of they had risen to 247 percent, Indicating an increase 33 24 in 1946-48. The prices of exports rose in the percent 24 Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 87, 1938-1949, 287. ?. as the values. same proportion average In December 1945 were of the export prices 194 percent 1938 By 25 Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 83, 1937-1947, 248. p. 51 December 1948 they had risen to 259 percent. This also The Board of Trade Journal, February 5, 1949. p. 259. indicates an increase of 53 percent in 1946-48. The observe tlons and explanations that were made above concerning the average values and prices of imports, also apply to the average values and prices of exports. The most notable, and most important. Increase in United Kingdom exports was in manufactured articles. In 1945 the volume of exports of British manufactures was 45 percent of the 1938 volume. In 1946 it stood at 111 percent of 1938, indicating an increase of 146 percent in one year. By 1948 exports of manufactures had risen to 155 percent of the 1938 volume, indicating an increase of 244 percent While in the three years, 1946-48 (see Chart these 27 The Board of Trade Journal, March 2. 1946, p. 220, February ISV 194?/ p'.’ "282, "and 'February 5# p. 233. figures represent an enormous gain, it must be remembered that the target set for exports of manufactures was about 100 percent above the 1938 voluem. In 1948, as shown above, percent above 1938. The value of exports they were only 55 of manufactures increased prodigiously. In 1945 It amounted 52 to 506.8 million pounds. By 1948, It had risen to 1,576.6 million pounds. While In 1945 the value was 84 percent of the 1938 value, in 1948 It was 277 percent. This represents an Increase of 250 percent In the value of exports of manu­2^ factures In the three years, 1946-48 (see Chart 2). 28 Annual Abstract of Statistics, Wo« 87, 1938-1949, p. 197-Tlie percentages indicating the rise In the value of exports of manufactures were computed by this writer. While the increase in total industrial production, especially in production of manufactures, and the vigorous export drive launched by the British Government were primar­ily responsible sharp In British exports, for the rise two other causes must be mentioned. First, Britain was selling her exports in a sellers' market, i.e., in a market in which demand far exceeded available supplies. The immediate post-war years saw an urgent need in many countries for capital goods to reconstruct war-ravaged industries and consumer goods of all kinds to meet war-deferred demands. Because of this high level of demand, a large increase in the volume of British sales was to be expected despite the high prices of exports. Secondly, the end of the war saw the disappearance of German and Japanese competition from market. The importance of this factor in Britain's the export export increase, however, is uncertain. It must be Chart 2. Volume and Value of United Kingdom Exports of Manufactures (1938=100) 54 remembered that Germany and Japan were importers as well as exporters before the war, and their ruin was almost certain to bring about a reduction of total world trade. Such a reduction would tend to be damaging rather than beneficial to Britain's export trade.^ 29 The Economist, November 3> 1945, p. 621. Achieving An Overall Balance While the value of British imports nearly doubled in the years from 1946 to 1948, the value of exports near­ ly quadrupled. Obviously, this would indicate a narrow­ ing of the trade and a healthy sign for Britain's gap balance matter of the of payments. As a fact, visible to the trade deficit, according figures given above, de­ clined from 658 million pounds in 1945 to 432 million in The current account section pounds of the United 30 The figure for 1945 is the one given in the first chapter. As calculated from the value of retained imports and the value of United Kingdom exports given above, the visible trade deficit for 1945 amounts to 653*7 million The for 1948 is obtained from the value of pounds. figure retained imports and the value of United Kingdom exports given for that year. above Kingdom general balance of payments, 1946-June 1950, as prepared by the British Treasury, shows that the trade 55 deficit was reduced to 1?6 million pounds in 1946, sharply increased to 425 million pounds in 1947, and again reduced to 31 207 million pounds in 1948. These figures, however, are 31 Cmd. 8065, United Kingdom Balance of Payments 1946 to 1950 (London; His Majesty's Stationery 6fftee7 October T§s(s), p. 7« based on yearly values of Imports and exports which differ considerably from those given in preceding pages. One of the chief reasons for this difference is the fact that imports and exports are both valued f.o.b. in the Treasury analysis, while in preceding pages imports are valued c.i.f. and ex­ ports f.o.b. Whatever the difference in the figures and the basis of their computation, it is clear that Britain's visible trade deficit was considerably reduced in the years from 1946 to 1948. More important, however, for its influence on the balance of payments, was the trend in Britain's invisible trade. As pointed out in the first chapter, there was a deficit of 172 million pounds in Britain's invisible trade in 1946. This was due primarily to the heavy overseas ex­ penditures of the Government (363 million pounds net). The visible and invisible trade deficits contributed to an over­ all balance-of-payments deficit of 348 million pounds in 1946. In 1947 the invisible trade deficit was reduced to 56 155 million pounds. The large visible trade deficit of 425 million pounds, however, made for an overall deficit of 558 million pounds. By 1948 net government overseas expend­ itures had been reduced to 87 million pounds, and Britain enjoyed a surplus in her Invisible trade of 127 million This pounds. surplus, coupled with a reduction to 207 million pounds in the visible trade deficit, reduced the over all deficit to 80 million pounds in 1948. Actually, a 52 Cmd. 8065, p. 7. balance in Britain’s current transactions had been attained in the second half of 1948. The Treasury’s analysis of the balance of payments, 1946-1949, shows that the visible trade deficit during the second half of 1948 had amounted to 44 million pounds, but a surplus of 89 million pounds in invisible trade, had resulted in an overall balance-of­ payments surplus of 43 million pounds for the half-year.^ 53 Cmd. 7795 , United Kingdom Balance of Payments 1946 to (London: His Majesty 1 s Stationery Office, October 19^9) P* 5» > Over the whole year, however, the overall balance was still in deficit. The attainment of a balance in Britain’s ex- the end of the must ternal payments by third post-war year 57 be regarded as a phenomenal achievement when It Is remembered that the overall deficit averaged about 700 million pounds during the war years. It could not have been attained with­ out great sacrifices on the part of the British people. In the first half of 1949 British imports and exports continued the upward trend which they had shown In the first three post-war years, 1946-48. Retained imports for the of first half-year 1949 were up to 85 percent of the 1938 volume, indicating an increase of 5 percent over 1948. United Kingdom exports rose to 151 percent of the 1938 volume, indicating an increase of 11 percent over 1948. The value of retained imports for the first half of 1949 amounted to 1,088.9 million pounds. This Indicates an increase of 68.4 million pounds over the last half of 1948. United Kingdom exports for the first half of 1949 were valued at 891.8 million pounds. This shows an increase of 52.0 million over the last half of 1948. The for the reason pounds greater increase in the value of Imports was a drop of 7 percent in the volume of exports from the first to the second of 1949, which kept down the value of exports for quarters 34 the half-year. 34 Calculated from figures in The Board of Trade Journal, August 6, P* 242. 58 The Treasury’s analysis of the United Kingdom general balance of payments, 1946-June 1950, values Imports at 958 million pounds (f.0.b.) and exports and re-exports at 915 million pounds (f.0.b.) for the first half of 1949. These figures make up a visible trade deficit of 43 million pounds for the half-year. Invisible trade for the same period, however, netted a surplus of 59 million pounds, making for an overall surplus of 16 million pounds In the balance of This surplus, although considerably 55 Cmd. 8065, p. 7* smaller than the one attained in the last half of 1948, main talned Britain’s solvent position In her external payments. The Dollar Deficit The attainment of a balance In Britain’s current transactions gave rise to much optimism In both Britain and the United States and led more enthusiastic spirits to economic believe that Britain's complete Independence had been achieved. There was, however, one important flaw In The was an overall balance and the situation. balance tended to conceal the continuing problem of Britain’s dol­ lar deficit. That is to It tended to conceal the fact say. 59 that Britain’s current dollar earnings were still inadequate to pay for her imports from the dollar area, and that the surpluses which she was with running elsewhere, e.g., Western Europe and the rest of the sterling area, could not he used to cover her deficit with the dollar countries. The problem was adequately stated in the Economic for Survey 1949, presented by the Chancellor of to the Exchequer Parliament in March 1949: The present general balance conceals a varied and complex pattern financial relationships. of With some countries, particularly the Western Hemisphere but also in the Middle East, we con­tinue to be heavily in deficit. With others, in­ cluding some of our partners in O.E.E.C. /Organiza­tion for European Economic Cooperation/ and a number of countries in the rest of the sterling area, we continue to have a large surplus. But as long as the non-dollar world remains critically short of dollars, it is not possible for us in general to earn from the countries with which we have surpluses the dollars which we need to finance our dollar deficit.^6 56 Cmd. 7647, Economic Survey for 1949 (London: His Majesty's Stationery Offfee, March P« 22. This deficit in current transactions with the dollar area remained the crucial problem in Britain's effort to attain full economic independence. The dollar deficit stemmed from the fact that while well as Britain's dollar experts (as exports in general) were necessarily limited during the reconversion period. 60 the bulk of her essential imports had to come from dollar countries because they were the only sources of supply at the time. In 1946 British exports to the dollar area amounted to only 98 million pounds ($396 million), while dollar im­amounted ports to 389 million pounds ($1,565 million). An invisible trade deficit of 4l million pounds ($167 million) made for a deficit of 332 million pounds ($1,336 million) with the dollar area. The overall balance-of-payments deficit in 1946 was 348 million pounds. In 194? dollar ex­ ports increased slightly to 127 million pounds ($512 million), but dollar imports substantially to 565 million Increased pounds ($2,279 million). The invisible trade deficit also increased substantially to 136 million pounds ($549 million), resulting in a dollar deficit of 574 million pounds ($2,316 overall balance- million). This figure was larger than the of-payments deficit of 558 million pounds for 1947* The year 1947 was the critical year. Thereafter, the dollar deficit began to diminish. In 1948 it was reduced to 273 million pounds ($1,105 million). For the first half of 1949 it amounted to 142 million pounds ($571 million). Thus, in the first half of 1949 while Britain was enjoying 16 she had a deficit an overall surplus of million pounds, ($571 million) with the dollar area. of 142 million pounds 57 Crad. 8065, pp. 8-9 and pp. 24-23. These figures are for the deficit in the balance of current transactions with the dollar area. into account Taking of other transactions the United Kingdom (investment, etc.), the dollar deficit of the rest of the sterling area, and the net gold and dollar payments made by the whole sterling area to other (non-dollar) countries, the total net gold and dol­ lar deficit amounted to 226 million pounds ($9OB million) in 1946, rose sharply to 1,024 million pounds ($4,131 million) in 1947> and then fell considerably to 423 million pounds ($1,710 million) in 1948. For the first half of 1949 it totalled 239 million pounds ($962 million)." 58 Cmd. 8065, pp. 24-25. The British Government took various steps to reduce limit the dollar deficit. These steps usually involved or restrictions on dollar imports and intensive efforts to ex­ pand exports to dollar markets. Import policy was concerned from dollar to non-dollar more with diverting purchases than with direct restrictions on dollar imports. In sources the Government to order to effect such a policy, took steps production in the non-dollar world, especially encourage and under-developed areas. Direct in the primary-producing work was carried on under Government auspices development and the Colonial Development the Overseas Food Corporation by 62 Corporation, and long-term contracts were made with primary producers guaranteeing them a market in other Commonwealth countries and in Europe. As a result of these measures. 39 Cmd. 7647, p. 29. which amounted imports from the Western Hemisphere, in 194-7 to 46 percent of total United Kingdom imports, were reduced to the pre-war (1938) proportion of 52 percent in 1948. Meanwhile, imports from the rest of the sterling area were increased from 53 percent of total imports in 1947 to 57 from the O.E.E.C. countries rose percent in 1948, imports from 15 percent to 18 percent, and imports from other 40 12 On the side countries rose from 6 percent to percent. 40 Ibid., p. 21. of the Government conducted a vigorous export drive exports, Practical assistance was on the North American market. given to Increase their salesto manufacturers and exporters eager markets. As a result, there was a In American and Canadian In exports to North America, and promisingnotable Increase for manufactures which had not been markets were built up United States or Canada before the war. Despite sold In the of total United Kingdom these efforts, however, the proportion to North exports going America remained slightly below the 41 pre-war level. United Kingdom exports to the Western 41 Crad. 7647, pp, 28-29. Hemisphere rose from 94 percent of the 1938 volume In 1947 to 139 percent In the last half of 1948, an Increase of 48 . 42 percent. 42 Ibid., p. 19* the British Government to with The efforts of cope the dollar deficit were meant to keep it from extending could not have been beyond manageable proportions. They to eliminate it completely, at least not in the designed short run. A large dollar deficit was, therefore, unavoid­ able, and the real problem was to find the means of financing it. To meet this problem, Britain had to rely chiefly on external aid. In the first two post-war years the bulk of the net gold and dollar deficit was met by drawings on the and Canadian loans. In 1946, 149 million pounds American drawn on the American loan and 130 were ($6OO million) on the Canadian loan. In million pounds ($523 million) 1947, with an enormous deficit of 1,024 million pounds million pounds ($2,850 ($4,131 million) to finance, 707 million) came from the United States line of and 43 In the second quarter of 194? drawings on the United States line of credit covered 236 million pounds ($950 million) of a quarterly deficit of 242 million pounds ($973 million). In the third quarter similar draw­ings covered 323 million pounds ($1,300 million) of a quarterly deficit of 381 million pounds ($1,537 million). 105 million pounds ($423 million) from the Canadian line of credit. The greater part of the remainder of the deficit was covered by drawings on Britain! s gold and dollar re­ -44 in the amount of 152 million pounds (s6lB million). serves 44 Cmd. 8065, pp. 26-27. States line of The heavy drawings on the United strain on the American loan funds. a credit put severe to last five the loan Although It had been expected years, In little more than a year after had virtually disappeared It melted away with amazing rapidity after It was granted. under terms of sterling convertibility was established, the 1947.^ the Financial Agreement, In July 45 "The British Crisis: A Problem J. H. Vol. Octo- Williams, In Economic Statesmanship", Foreign Affairs, 28, ber 1949, P-4. to finance the dollar deficit While the drawings Inroads on the loan, there were other more made heavy for important reasons Its rapid exhaustion. Professor 1 Lionel in Fobbins, an article in Lloyds Bank Review^ 46 Robbins, L. "inquest on the Crisis”, Lloyds Bank Review, New Series, October 194?, pp. 1-2?. offers three explanations. First, the greater rise in im­ port prices relative to export prices, i.e., a deteriora­ tion of of the terms trade against Britain, following the ratification of the Financial Agreement, produced "a fall in the purchasing power of the loan, a shrinkage in the which it made breathing space possible." Secondly, the un­ settled world conditions of the post-war period called for the heavy government expenditures overseas "on maintenance of essential of armed forces and the provision supplies." Both of these factors caused a serious drain on British this is Professor Robbins’ main resources. Thirdly (and a explanation of the loan’s exhaustion), there was colossal of capital from the United Kingdom, chiefly to the leakage area in the form of substantial withdrawals of the sterling The facts seem to substantiate Mr. sterling balances. the of In Robbins' arguments concerning leakage capital. inflow of 1946 there was a net capital 194 million pounds. 1947 the United Kingdom experienced a net capital out- In flow million pounds. The non-sterling area, princi­ of 302 pally the United States and Canada, contributed a net 66 capital inflow of 14 million pounds to the United Kingdom. On the hand, the a sterling area acquired capital out­ flow of 316 million pounds from United Kingdom,^ the 47 Ellis, H. S. "The Dollar Shortage in Theory and Fact The , Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Vol* 3cience, 14, August 1945, pT JUUI Professor Robbins puts a substantial share, but not all, of the blame for the on flight of capital convertibility. He notes that the rate of withdrawal after July 15, 1947, when went convertibility into effect, greatly exceeded the rate of withdrawal prior to that date. He points out, however, that convertibility, per se, was not completely responsible for the loss of capital: The convertibility obligation,...was an obligation to maintain not but total convertibility only con­vertibility on current account. This means in plain English that the foreigner was entitled to tu~n in­ to dollars, if he pleased, not his capital but his current earnings. 48 Robbins, loc. clt., p. 18. of that His implication is, course, it was convertibility of withdrawals over and above current earnings, and not con- that was to blame for the vertibility itself, tremendous of capital. The effect of the withdrawals of leakage 49 Ibid., pp. 15-19. sterling balances, converted into dollars, on the American be loan fund, can appreciated when It Is noted that of the capital outflow of J>l6 million pounds going to the sterling area, 266 million pounds were used to cover the area f s dol­ lar deficit, thus making for a loss of dollars not only by but the whole the United Kingdom by sterling area. 50 There 50 Ellis, loc. cit., p. 366. Is no doubt that the primary effect of sterling convertlbll Ity was to accelerate the dollar drain. It was this ad­ ditional strain on Britain's dwindling dollar resources that brought about the suspension of convertibility on weeks after Its The August 20, just five Inception. Economist, absolving the Government of much of the blame, saId: This particular objective to restore convertibil­ity unilaterally by July 15th last was not a chosen objective nor was it a party objective. It was an Inescapable part of the price for a loan which most people were agreed Britain had to have, a which Britain honestly tried to pay, but price which was so high that It was all too likely to break the bank. It would certainly have done so within a few days had Britain decided that very In the extremity It had to stand by even present the letter of the bond. During the month of July, the sand In the dollar hour-glass was running out at rate of sl7i million per day. In the frightening decision the seven working days before the new was taken the dally loss was at just twice that rate million was lost In the five days to August $176 million In the first two days of this 15th and $66 68 week. such a At rate, the US dollar credit would have run out early next month /Septem­ ber 19477.51 51 The Economist, August 23, 19*7, p. 331. The virtual exhaustion of the American loan towards the end of 194? left Britain without her chief of means not financing only her persistent dollar deficit but also her overall balance-of-payments deficit. The tremendous rise of the net gold and dollar deficit from 226 million pounds (S9OB million) in 1946 to 1,024 million pounds ($4,131 million) in 194? and the rise of the over-all def­ icit from 348 million pounds in 1946 558 million pounds to in 1947, rendered Britain's position critical. the But, British difficulty was only a part of the general economic crisis that engulfed Western Europe in 1947. This crisis the intense of was precipitated by winter 1946-47 which caused wide-spread crop failures and heavy cuts in coal supplies. It was characterized by enlarged dollar deficits, internal inflation, and, consequently, political instabil­ in most of the countries on the Continent. This situa­ ity tion led to the of the Marshall Plan adoption for long­ term assistance by the United States to Western Europe. On the basis of the report prepared by the 16-nation Committee at Paris of European Economic Cooperation in September 1947, President Truman submitted to Congress in December a long-range program of assistance for European recovery. After lengthy debate, Congress passed the Economic Coopera­ tion Act, embodying the President's proposals. In April The European Recovery Program (the designa­ official tion for the Marshall Plan) was more than just another post-war loan or grant to Europe. It was an attempt to Integrate American aid with European economic cooperation and self-help. Its chief alms were to Increase Industrial production and create Internal financial stability In the and to attain a of participating countries solution Europe's dollar problem. As a result of Marshall aid, European recovery proceeded rapidly. Industrial production rose above the pre-war level, the Inflationary spiral re­ ceded and Internal economic stability was gradually achieved, and Europe's foreign trade expanded considerably. The funds made available to the United Kingdom took the place of through the European Recovery Program the American loan as the chief medium for financing Britain's deficit. In 169 million pounds ($682 million) dollar dollar deficit met E.R.P. funds. were of the net gold and by Of the remainder of the deficit, 80 million pounds ($325 the South African Gold Loan and million) were covered by (In the first quarter of the year) million pounds ($3OO loan. the last drawings on the American In the million) by first half of 1949 E.R.P. funds covered 165 million pounds of the ($665 million) deficit for the half-year. Gold and dollar reserves covered 51 million pounds ($205 million). Cmd. 7928, United Kingdom Balance of Payments 1946 r Hfs to lp49j No. 2 (London; MaJesTy Stationery Office, s Aprfl I9sff)V PP* 7 and 9; Cmd. 8065, pp. 26-27­ These indicate clearly vital figures the role played by Marshall aid in Britain's recovery efforts. Without the funds provided by E.R.P., Britain would have been forced to cut her dollar imports even more drastically than she was already doing through the policy of Import restriction and diversion. The E.R.P. receipts permitted her to con­ tinue those imports of food and raw materials essential to the completion of the reconversion program and available in the dollar countries. only Loss of Gold and Dollar Reserves The 1949 Crisis: By the middle of Britain was enjoying a and more stable external position than she had stronger time since the end of the war. Her experienced at any industrial recovery had been achieved with amazing suc­ her export trade was increasing rapidly, and for the cess, before the war she had achieved overall first time since in her current international transactions. In viability of Commons delivered in the House on July 6, 19^9, a speech Slt» Stafford Crlpps, Chancellor of summarized the Exchequer, the situation In terms: happy Today, as a result of the conclusion of the Brussels Pact, the establishment of the OEEC /Organization for European Economic Recover17 and the signature of the Atlantic Pact, our own position and that of the other countries con­ cerned has been immeasurably strengthened. We have behind In the us United Kingdom two of years expenditure on capital goods on an unprecedented scale, and of uninterrupted eco­nomic progress. We have taken a variety of measures to deal with the in inflationary situation with which 19*47 we were threatened. Our production is at a record level in the whole of our history, and our exports are as high as they have ever been as and half as high again in mid-1947* We have practically reached a state of over­all balance In our overseas trade. All this has been made possible by the great efforts of our own people and by generous help the of the United States and Canada, especially through the European Recovery Program which Is so large a factor In the progress that Is being made 55 Vital Speeches of the Day, Vol. XV, July 15, 19^9, p. 585. these favorable signs, the situation But, despite contained certain disturbing aspects which presaged a new crisis In Britain’s international payments position. By mld-194-9 the sellers' market for British exports had dis­ appeared. European production, as mentioned above, had been raised above the pre-war level, and, consequently, for British goods which had characterized the urgent demand had fallen off In the Immediate post-war period the Western 72 European countries. had British exports, which previously been absorbed on the basis then had to of need alone, compete on the basis of quality and price considerations. In other words, the sellers’ market had given way to a buyers’ market. Such a change in demand conditions por­ tended a probable decline in Britain’s export trade. Further­ more, British imports, already severely restricted, could withstand further cuts not without endangering production targets and without increasing the burden of austerity. A reduction of exports, in such circumstances, would certainly the small overall surplus that had been achieved in erase the balance of payments. A more serious development, however, was the un­ favorable turn in Britain’s dollar position in the first of Despite the sharp decline in the net six months 19*19. and dollar deficit from 194? to 1948, there was a gold rise in the first half of 1949 over the last considerable 1948. For the last six months of 1948 the deficit half of amounted to 169 million pounds (s6Bl million), while for It amounted to million months of 1949 239 the first six pounds ($962 million). There was an even sharper rise from the second quarters of 1949. During the first the first to deficit totalled 82 million pounds ($330 mil- quarter the the second quarter it totalled 156 lion), while during 73 sty million pounds ($632 million). The first six months of 54 Cmd. 7928, pp. 7 and 9; Cmd. 8065, pp. 26-27. 1949 thus Indicated a reversal of the favorable trend that the previous year had shown in the status of the dollar deficit. It is significant that in the same period when an Britain was enjoying overall balance in her current transactions, her dollar deficit was again increasing, and although the problem of financing an overall deficit had been obviated for the time being, the problem of financing the dollar deficit remained. The latter problem became ex­ tremely disquieting when the dollar deficit increased beyond the funds made available to Britain and the sterling area under E.R.P., through the Canadian loan, and through the International Monetary Fund. In the second quarter of on the Canadian loan and E.R.P. 1949 drawings receipts (there were no drawings on IMF) covered only 91 million pounds ($570 million) of a quarterly deficit of 156 mil­ lion pounds ($652 million). The remainder, 65 million pounds ($262 million), was met from the gold and dollar reserves 55 of the sterling area. As a result, the reserves fell 55 Ibid. 74 from a total of 471 million pounds ($1,912 million) as of March 31 to 406 million pounds ($1,651 million) as of June This was in contrast to the situation in the first 56 Cmd. 8065, p. 28. quarter of 1949. During that period drawings on the Canadian loan and on IMF and E.F.P. receipts amounted to 96 million pounds ($586 million). This sum exceeded the quarterly deficit of 82 million pounds ($550 million) by 14 million and the and pounds ($3B million), gold dollar holdings were increased by the latter amount. In the fourth quarter of 1948 gold and dollar holdings had been increased by 20 million pounds ($79 million).^ 57 Cmd. 7928, pp. 7 and 9; Cmd. 8055, pp. 26-27. The drain on reserves in the second quarter of 1949 called for immediate corrective action by the Government. Such action was indeed being taken by the middle of 1949. Said Chancellor Crtpps in his July speech to the Commons: His Majesty's Government....acted at once in pursuance of what must remain the major objective of our financial policy, the safeguarding of the reserves of the sterling area. Before the middle of June we had, much to our to regret, been compelled by events give 75 instructions to all our purchasing depart­ments that they were to postpone new dollar to the maximum extent purchases practicable. That standstill arrangement will be continued for at least three months and until after the discussions to which I am about to refer with John W. Snyder, Secretary of the United States Treasury, and Douglas C. Abbott, Cana­dian Minister of Finance, and the conference of Commonwealth Finance Ministers/. Existing contracts and committments will remain in force, but will be specific authority required for any new dollar purchases and will only be given where a clear case of urgent national interest is established. Dollar expend­iture, other than on imports, will only be per­mitted where essential, and then at a reduced rate. Unless the sterling area succeeds in re­storing the volume of its sales to the dollar area, these restrictions upon dollar expenditure will have to be continued.s° 58 Vital Speeches of the Day, Vol. July 15, 1949, p. 585. Early in July, talks were held between British Government officials, John ¥. Snyder, Secretary of the United States Treasury, and Douglas C. Abbott, Canada’s Finance Minister. On July 13 a conference of Commonwealth Finance Ministers was convened in London. The purpose of these meetings was to hold high-level discussions on Britain's dollar problem and to devise short-term corrective measures. On July 14 Sir Stafford Crlpps announced that the United Kingdom's dollar imports would be reduced by 25 percent in 1949-50. this the Following announcement, the final communique on 76 Commonwealth conference stated that "the Ministers con­ cerned agreed to recommend to their Governments action comparable in its results to that already decided upon by the United Kingdom*" The Cripps announcement referred to the Government's plans for reducing the United Kingdom's million dollar purchases from 400 million pounds to 300 at pounds per annum, i.e., to save dollars a rate of 100 million pounds per annum. The agreement by the Common­ wealth conference implied a reduction in Commonwealth im­ ports from North America by between $7OO million and $950 59 million. 59 The Statist, July 25, PP-lO5-106. These measures, as well as the standstill on dol­ lar purchases announced by Sir Stafford Cripps in his speech of July 6, were, however, mere stop-gap devices. of the They contained no permanent solution problem, and they could not be expected to have any immediate effect in the drain on Britain's dollar resources. halting Indeed, the loss of gold and dollar reserves continued and soon reached alarming proportions. Late in August It was esti­ mated that the gold and dollar drain during the third quarter would reach the 100 million pounds level. This would represent an Increase of 50 percent over the loss recorded in the second quarter and would reduce the reserve to a 60 mere 300 million pounds by the end of September. ' By 60 The Statist, August 27, 19*19, p. 251. September 18 this estimate was well on the way to proving correct. On that date, the gold and dollar reserves were 61 down to 330 million pounds million). This sum 61 Cmd. 8065, p. 28. was well below the 500 million pounds (about $2,000 million) which was the figure generally regarded as the safety level for Britain's reserves. It was in this atmosphere of growing crisis that Sir Stafford Cripps and Foreign Secretary Ernest Bevin to journeyed to Washington early in September begin talks with American and Canadian representatives for the purpose of in as- discussing the sterling-dollar problem its broader pects and arriving at some permanent solution of Britain's dollar difficulties. Much of the groundwork for this meet­ ing had already been laid in the Cripps-Snyder-Abbott talks the conference of Commonwealth Finance Ministers held and During the weeks between those deliberations and in July. the opening of the Washington talks, the British Government had surveyed the whole dollar problem and reached some very Important decisions concerning its solution. It was these decisions that the Cripps-Bevin delegation took to Washington for discussion. Chapter III DEVALUATION OF THE POUND STERLING The Washington conference opened on September 7, amid much speculation on both sides of the Atlantic and indeed throughout the whole world. From the beginning, close secrecy was maintained concerning the content of the discussions. The attitude of the United States and Cana­ dian governments appeared to be that the crisis was primar­ ily the result of British policy failures, and that re­ sponsibility for finding a solution lay with the British Government. The intention of the American and Canadian representatives, therefore, was to listen to, to consider, and to discuss the proposals of the British delegates, rather than to submit any proposals of their own. Further- the concensus of public opinion in the United States more, was opposed to further monetary aid to the United Kingdom. This view, no doubt influenced by the feeling that American dollars were being used to subsidize British socialism, was shared by official elements. The Congress, partly in deference to public opinion and partly on its own account, was definitely opposed to any extension of the foreign aid The Administration was of the opinion that what program. was needed to meet the crisis was not further dollar aid 79 to Britain but an adjustment of British economic policies by the British Government itself. The Washington cor­ respondent for The Statist, writing on the eve of the conference, observed: When the Anglo-American Financial Agreement and the Marshall plan were ih the making there was uncertainty and disagreement over amounts and methods of financing, but there was no doubt, so far as the U.S. Government was concerned, that they would offer, indeed had to offer, a large sum of money to cover badly needed exports. To-day, the reverse is true; there is a great reluctance, partly inspired by Congress, to suggest any new direct assistance to the United Kingdom. more, government What is this obvious­ ly feels the United Kingdom should be held chief­ly responsible for finding ways to increase her dollar receipts expenditures. l or reduce her 1 The Statist, August 27, P« 256. The Basic Causes of Devaluation For some time, informed circles in Britain had also shared the opinion that certain fundamental changes in British policy rather than stop-gap dollar aid was the prime need in dealing with the problem. Thus, it was be­ lieved that the root of the British crisis lay not in the drain on gold and dollar reserves but in the new conditions of world trade and Britain’s inability to adjust to those conditions. This new situation in world trade was the result of 81 the restoration of European industrial production, particu­ larly production for export, and, consequently, the emer­ gence of the buyers' market. The competitive nature of such a market dictated an improvement in the quality, and, more Importantly, a reduction in the selling prices, of British exports. As more and more war-time technological innovations were adopted and as productive facilities and techniques were improved during the course of the recon­ version process, a high degree of quality in British ex­ ports was reasonably assured. British export prices, how- remained high in relation to world market prices. ever, The danger of high prices to Britain's export trade was foreseen even before the appearance of the new market con­ ditions. In March Mr. G. D. A. MacDougall, a British economist, pointed out that "the quantity of exports we /Britain/ can sell will depend greatly on the price at which we sell them," and that "unless we can sell at competitive prices our exports will sooner or later suffer."2 2 MacDougall, G. D. A. "Britain's Foreign Trade Problem", Economic Journal, Vol. LVII, March p. 107. in the same The Economist advised: Later year means or another the prices at which one By British goods are quoted in the world market have got to be reduced to a level at which, quality for quality, they attract and do not No one can estimate how large a re- repel. duction in costs and prices will be needed. But as guide it be said that a very rough may cut In present British export prices of any cent is less than 30 per hardly worth looking at.5 3 The Economist, September 27, 1947, p. 512. A year later The Economist, anticipating a buyers’ market, warned that British exports would have to undercut world prices in order to overcome the competition: It is difficult to reach any conclusion about whether British exports are, at present, com- is, about whether they would be petitive—that competitive if there were any competition. The evidence is conflicting. But there is no evi­ dence at all that they are undercutting the market. Moreover, buyers' comes, when the market there are other countries that will prove many much nimbler at reducing their prices than 2* Britain. 4 The Economist, September 25, 1948, p. 483­ By early 1949 the sellers 1 market was definitely at an end, and the problem of selling British exports at prevailing became real. The Economic Survey for 1949 cited prices the '’difficulties of finding buyers at our present selling of the three main limitations on British ex- as one prices” The Survey continued: ports. Demand is falling off in some markets and for some classes of goods where restocking is now completed. same increasing compe- At the time has to be tition from other exporters faced markets.s in the main hard currency 5 Cmd. 7647, Economic Survey for 1949 (London: His Majesty's Stationery office, March 1949),p. 18. In July Sir Hubert Henderson, Professor of Political Economy at Oxford, wrote; and ....over a large increasing range of trade, British goods are far too dear for effective competition in buyers' markets. As the costs of and of production the selling prices Indus­trial commodities fall in the United States, In Belgium, and elsewhere, this disparity grows and becomes more glaring. To correct it is imperative; otherwise it will be impossible to avert a continuous shrinking in the volume of British export trade, at first to dollar or semi-dollar markets, but extending gradually everywhere. 3 6 f, 1"* Moral Henderson, SiHubert, The of the British Cr is is", The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XXXI, November tgr?;‘prss7; the between British and world While disparity prices was sufficient cause for concern, the gap between British and dollar prices was even more distressing. The Economist saw a serious threat to Britain’s dollar exports in the latter gap; It is becoming clearer every day that there is a great and growing divergence between the level of costs and prices in the sterling and dollar areas. An interesting article in last week's Investor '3 Chronicle quoted the results of an inquiry by the Trinidad Chamber of Com­ merce into the prices of certain consumer goods as landed In that Island from the United Kingdom as with the similar compared same or goods from the United States or Canada. The list is too long to be but quoted here, in general it shows a very decided price advantage in favour of the North American products. British electrical goods, for example—the sort of on which thing so much reliance is placed in the export drive- are stated to be “on the average 100 per cent dearer than the American or Canadian articles.” Other similar evidence is from coming in daily all over the world. This is a serious situation for a very country whose whole future is staked on its abil­ ity to export. It is clear that with price dis­crepancies of this order-widening as American prices fall--it will be difficult to hold British sales in the dollar area itself, and that the in­ creases talked of in the out long-term plan are of the question. 7 7 The Economist, May 7, 1949, p. 825. On the eve of devaluation. The Statist pointed out that High prices may not constitute the whole of the dollar problem, but high prices of British ex- at to ports are certainly present helping restrict dollar sales. 0 8 The Statist, September 17, P-3^s* And Sir Stafford Cripps, in a broadcast to the British people announcing the devaluation of sterling on September 18, 1949, explained: Some of our export prices to dollar markets have been too high, and in a number of cases those markets did not bring a good enough return to encourage our manufacturers and exporters to 85 expand their dollar exports. It was pretty clear, in the light of the experience of the last few months, that without a marked reduc­tion in the dollar price of our exports and an increase in our sales we pressure, were running a most serious risk that our dollar earnings would not be high enough to maintain the flow of essential imports so as to keep up our standard of production and living. 9 9 of Vol. October Vital Speeches the Day, XV, 1, 1949, PP. 739-7TOT" It was thus the apparent inability of British export to adjust to the conditions of a and prices buyers’ market, especially the discrepancy between sterling and dollar that informed opinion in Britain took to be the prices, fundamental cause of Britain's external payments problem. root The conviction that high export prices were at the of . the trouble led to a great deal of speculation on the merits of of of devaluation the pound as a possible means lowering British prices in terms of foreign currencies. The Govern­ ment itself shunned devaluation and devoted its efforts to reducing production costs and, therefore, prices by en- in couraging greater productivity and efficiency industry. Despite the improved productivity and efficiency which was indeed attained in British industry, the expected reduction in costs was not achieved. The greatest obstacle to such reduction appears to have been the inability of the Govern a ment to keep wages down. "The biggest item in most firms' 86 costs," said The Economist, "is wages, and no serious cut In wage rates Is economically conceivable under a regime of full employment or politically conceivable under almost 0 any regime at all."'1Another deterrent to cost reduction * 10 The Economist, July 51, P* 171. See also The Economist, May 7] p. 826. was the high prices of certain raw materials used by British Industry. ll 11 The Statist, September 17, p. s^s* The persistency of high prices despite the improved efficiency in production intensified the discussion and speculation on the desirability of devaluation as a remedy to the problem. As early as March Mr. G. D. A. MacDougall observed: ....the fact that our exports are by no means unresponsive to changes In the value of sterling points to the need of preserving our right to If this Is likely, at depreciate sterling any future time, to help restore our International 12 equilibrium. 12 MacDougall, loc. cit., pp. 107-108. Mr. MacDougall pointed out, however, that sterling deprecla tlon could not always be relied upon to restore equilibrium Our exports are not, of course, the only item in our balance of payments affected by a de­ preciation of sterling. The latter will, in particular, tend to raise the sterling price of our and unless this reduces imports; pro-the of portionately quantity our imports—which is unlikely in view of their essential nature-­ the total import bill, in terras of sterling, will Increase. This will offset, in part or in whole, 1* the higher sterling receipts from our exports. 15 MacDougall, loc. cit., p. 108. Most of the arguments on the side of devaluation centered on the idea that such step would obviouslya lower British export prices and thus increase the volume of exports. This idea rested on the assumption that there was an elastic demand for British exports. Mr. Howard 3. Ellis, an American economist, was one of the few who recognized and elaborated on that assumption. He wrote; The favorable case rests.... upon an elastic de­ mand and the expansion of volume of trade, both exports and imports, such that values--quantity times price per unit—are greater. Those who that devaluation is inadvisable now be- argue cause of the inelastic supply of British export; ""demand necessarily imply that the is elastic, since upon the contrary assumption, England** could profitably restrict exports even below with this their present level. I agree impli­cation: England’s diversified industrial prod­ucts, and services of a professional, business, and commercial nature bid fair to enjoy an elastic demand.^ 14 Ellis, H. 3. "The Dollar Shortage in Theory and Fact”, The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Vol. Science, In May 1949 The Economist noted that "the dollar prices at which British goods are quoted could be lowered by an alteration in the exchange value of the pound sterling." But while thus admitting the usefulness of devaluation in reducing British export prices. The Economist warned that ....it would be rash to draw much comfort very from that prospect, for unless the causes that lead to high costs of production in Britain are removed, any relief that could be secured by devaluation would be purely temporary.ls 15 The Economist, May 28, p. 971. John K. Williams, Professor of Political Economy at Harvard, in an article written on the eve of devaluation, not only regarded sterling devaluation as "the most obvtous....man­ ner of attacking the problem directly, but 16 Williams, J. H. "The British Crisis: A Problem in Economic Statesmanship", Foreign Affairs, Vol. 28, October 19^9> P* 12. believed that such a step might become necessary: ....I have been inclining to the view (as an in- economists seem to creasing number of English do) at will be that sterling devaluation, some stage, a necessary part of the process of adjusting the imbalance between the sterling and the dollar areas, and, rightly handled, could contribute im- It would portantly to all-round trade adjustment. probably lead the way to an all-round adjustment this at of exchange rates, and might overcome, least the bias in world trade that temporarily, Itself in the universal dollar shortage. expresses 89 The fact Is that the dollar needs to be ap­preciated; and this seems the practicable most way of doing It. ' 17 Williams, loc. clt., p. 15. Profes- Such conviction did not, however, completely remove sor Williams 1 doubts concerning the effectiveness of devalue tion. He admitted that ’'much could be accomplished without is much devaluation, and what it would Itself accomplish in terms of more uncertain than a simple analysts purchasing 18 power parities and comparative costs would suggest.” 18 Ibid., p. 13* It Is apparent that those who regarded devaluation obvious method of with of sterling as a logical and dealing the problem of high export prices, almost Invariably quali­ out fied their opinions by pointing the dangers and uncer­ tainties of devaluation and the temporary character of any benefits which it might bring. devaluation were legion. One The arguments against these was that devaluation of sterling of the most common of set off a wave of currency depreciations similar to would as The Economist that of the 1930’5. As early opposed devaluation on this score: ....it /devaluation/ cannot be expected to make dear British exports cheap. A large num­ber of the world's currencies are or formally Informally tied to sterling and would fall with It. Many others would follow. And when the pound depreciated In 1931 it was followed In­side eighteen months by the dollar Itself. De­valuation of sterling would be of relatively minor Importance to the balance of payments. It certainly does not provide an alternative to the hard way of making British goods at­tractive . 19 The Economist, September 27, 1947, p. 512. A year later The Economist again warned that "the pound sterling, if it were devalued, would be followed down by most of the other currencies of the world," and that in the 1930’s "the pound was out-devalued by the dollar itself OA the within eighteen months." And Professor Williams, in 20 The Economist, September 25, 1948, p. 484. article mentioned above, considered one of the dangers same sterling devaluation to be "setting off an external of circle of spiral in the form of a vicious currency deprecla itself. tions feeding on 21 Williams, loc. cit., p. 13. This concern over a probable chain reaction In the wake of devaluation based that sterling was on the fear such a reaction would Include the dollar. It Is to be remembered that Britain had a surplus on current account with most of the OEEC countries and the rest of the sterling area. A fall in the exchange value of these countries 1 currencies equal to the fall In the value of the pound would. It was believed, leave British export prices In terms of those currencies unchanged, Britain's ability to export to those countries unimpaired, and the surplus on current account unaffected. With the dollar area, however, Britain had a persistent deficit. A fall In the value of the dol­ lar would nullify any stimulus to Britain’s dollar exports resulting from lower British export prices in terms of dollars, and the dollar deficit would continue undimlnlshed. be Sterling devaluation, it was felt, could effective only if the value of the dollar remained unchanged. Professor Williams observed; The best defense against another vicious circle would be for the dollar this of depreciations time to stand firm. And the best answer to the to make a new sterling rate question of how would be carry conviction of permanence for the United States to help suoport it. Indeed, it seems clear that If we /the United States/ ad­ vise devaluation we should take definite ob- a to cooperate in making it effective. ligation 22 Williams, loe. cit., p. 15* Another major argument against devaluation was that It would have an inflationa-ry effect on Britain’s internal Sir Hubert Henderson believed that economy. it would aggravate the inflationary situation that already existed: If a substantial devaluation were to be followed by a fully proportionate rise in the level of wages and sterling costs, clearly it would do nothing to reduce the price disparity sterling and dollar pricey/. Doubtless this would be an extreme result; but any rise in prices and costs would pro tanto defeat the ob­ ject of the devaluation, and in existing circum­stances the rise would almost certainly be sub­ stantial. The British labor market is still a sellers' market, and gives the trade unions a strong bargaining position, they ex- which have ploited only in part. In these circumstances, the would be great that devaluation danger very would lead to a vicious spiral of a rising cost of living, rising wages and costs of production, and further devaluation. The definite elimination of the inflationary trend in our economy must, in my opinion, precede devaluation of sterling. Only when this has any been done will It be possible to judge the ex­tent of the devaluation that may be appropriate; and only then will it be possible to feel reason­ably confident that the readjustment will be final.23 23 Henderson, loc. clt., pp. 257-258. Similar fears were expressed by Professor Williams: was In 1931 this danger /Inflation/ slight because the world generally, was in a state Britain, like 93 of depression, with unemployed resources. This fact, combined with the circumstance that she a was large and then unrestricted Import market, caused external prices to fall rather than British prices to rise as a result of the de­valuation. But now both circumstances are re­versed. Britain still suffers from over-full employment and low real Income, and her Imports are so restricted that the already possibility that she can again push the economic burden of sterling devaluation onto other countries seems remote. This means not only that the corrective effect of the devaluation on the external balance would have to come, this time, almost purely from the export side, but that much sterner measures would have to be taken to prevent the devaluation from being dissipated by an Internal wage-price spiral. 24 2k Williams, loc. clt., p. 13. of devaluation based Some opponents their opposi­ tion on doubts that by lowering export prices the volume of could be increased. exports Thus, by implication they doubted the existence of an elastic demand for British goods. "It is exceedingly unlikely," Mr. Thomas Balogh, a British economist, pointed out in "that devaluation would increase the volume of our exports, as they are now determined by 'market forces. ’ &^d later a similar view 23 Balogh, T. "Britain's P’orelgn Trade Problem: A Comment", Economic Journal, Vol. LVIII, March 1948, footnote 83. p. 94 wag expressed by Sir Hubert Henderson: With the of disappearance sellers’ markets, a reduction of British selling prices would not be followed by a larger volume of sales than hitherto, essential though It Is in order to check a continuous decline. On the most favor­able hypotheses In the prevailing state of trade, we must reckon with a considerable drop In our export recelpts,.... 26 Henderson, loc. cit., p. 257. Still another argument against devaluation was that the resultant higher of British In of prices Imports terms sterling would not operate to reduce the volume of Imports, since these were already restricted to bare essentials. An unchanged volume of Imports at higher Import prices would obviously offset the larger earnings on the side of exports. Said Mr. Balogh; Britain Is Importing In the main staple commodi­ties which have world markets. The quantity of our Imports is not governed by Internal money demand but by Government decision. A devalua­ tion of Itself cut sterling would not by imports (and a cut of Imports can be effected without devaluation). Hence devaluation would not exert pressure on our import prices In terms of foreign currency, which would, therefore. In terms of sterling increase fully In proportion to the rate of the devaluation.-' 27 Balogh, loc. clt., footnote p. Sj>. Cf. MacDougall, 108. loc. clt., p. 95 The Statist regarded ,fthe Increase In the cost of Imported goods and raw materials leading to a rise In sterling costs neutralise (which would partly the down pressure on export prices exerted by devaluation)" as one of the chief dis­ pO advantages of sterling devaluation. ~~ — i ¦ » ¦ ¦--—¦—» . -^'—¦ -»¦—¦ —— *r ,m-~ 28 The Statist, May 7, 1949, P-498. The Statist voiced serious doubts that devaluation would Increase the dollar earnings of the stealing area as a whole: truth is that there is no indication that the reduction in the value of the pound would in­crease the overall return from sterling-area sales all the evidence is to the The to the United States; contrary.^9 29 The Statist, March 19, P* 299* the same ad Shortly thereafter, journal warned that despite that might accrue to the United ditional dollar earnings a result of the stimulus to its dollar exports. Kingdom as ....the net effect of a devaluation of stealing and an accompanying devaluation in terms of the dollar of its associated currencies would probab­ be to produce an actual contraction in over­ ly all dollar yields. 3o 50 The Statist, May 7, p. 498. And on the eve of the Washington conference, it pointed out Since the fall in the dollar earnings of the sterling area has been due to the shrink­age of receipts from the sale of products like wool, rubber and cocoa, which sell at world prices, rather than to a decline in sales of manufactured goods caused by over-pricing, there is no certainty that devaluation would effect a n indeed Mr. cu e, as Hoffman, the Marshall warned this week. Even if it did achieve some net in plan administrator, expansion dollar earnings a sizeable deficit would per­slst,...3l 31 The Statist, August 27, p. 251. The majority of those who stood against sterling devaluation did so not because they opposed devaluation as such, but because they doubted its efficacy In dealing with the British problem at the time. Most of them never out rates ruled the readjustment of exchange as a possible at and. Indeed, necessary measure some future date. In the words of The Economist: "....there is no present at case all for devaluation, and the most that anybody can say is that there may be a case for it before very long."^2 Even 32 The Economist, May 7 p. 825. , that leaned to the side of devaluation not those were so sure that the time was propitious for such a step. The gist of the argument seemed, therefore, to be not whether devaluation per se was the remedy to Britain’s ills, but whether the time was right for undertaking the readjustment of currency values which the new conditions of world trade seemed to dictate. Both sides were apparently more con­ cerned with the timing of devaluation, should it become necessary, than with its effects which everyone considered uncertain. highly In the United States, official opinion not only favored but in fact urged sterling devaluation early in of 1949* In May that year The Statist commented: It is becoming increasingly clear that Britain is being placed under considerable pres­sure by the United States Economic Co-operation Administration and by a section of the Organiza­tion for European Economic Co-operation both to carry out a devaluation of sterling in terms of the American dollar and to permit unlimited use of sterling in connection with a scheme of gen- currencies.^ eral interconvertibility of European 33 The Statist, May 21, p. 562. The United States Treasury, convinced that a general read­ justment of currencies was inevitable and although well of was most aware the dangers involved, energetic in urging sterling This attitude, however, underwent 34 The Statist, June 4, 194 pp. 632-633­ a sudden change on the eve of the Washington talks. The change was apparently brought on by the realization by American officials that too much their part prompting on would tend to throw responsibility for the success or failure of devaluation on the United States. The Washington correspondent for The Statist reported; It can be predicted fairly surely that the United States will not urge devaluation. They will suggest this move only by inference, Indicat­that they do not feel that the ing trade problem can be solved so long as the pound Is valued at a rate that Is not more generally accepted. All this means that the United States Is reluctant to stick its neck out In favour of any scheme of Its own for fear that It will not succeed. Underlying this fear Is still another; that It may not be possible politically or Intel­lectually for the United Kingdom to move In the direction of freer trade, freer markets at home and abroad and a cheaoer It Is currency. this doubt that Sir Stafford will have to overcome first of all If he Is to succeed. In this connection iu is important to realise that the United States does not regard devaluation as a solution in itself, or even the main needed to as ingredient improve trade. The N. A. C. /National Advisory has made this clear to the United States very nego­ tiators. They are not likely, therefore, to put themselves in a spot where they appear to urge only devaluation, Sir Stafford appears to bow to this one wish, and they then assume responsi­dollar drain that bility for making good any continues after the pound is cheapened. Some officials go so far as to predict if the that British delegates should propose devaluation they will not be told whether the United States until the matter for discussion by the board directors of the International approves comes up o£ Monetary Fund.^s 55 The Statist, August 27, pp. 256-257. For a long time the British Government, as pointed this remained firm in out earlier in chapter, its opposi­ tion to devaluation, even when its efforts to solve the problem of high prices through a reduction of production costs proved unsuccessful. Early in May Sir Stafford Cripps, at a press conference in Rome, reaffirmed the Government’s determination to avoid a devaluation of the pound. Clearly and emphatically, he declared that what­ ever course other currencies might take, a devaluation of “neither would it take c sterling was necessary nor place."^ 36 The Economist, May 7, P» 825* Prior to his departure for Washington, Sir Stafford re­ iterated this stand when, according to reports, he assured other Cabinet Ministers that devaluation would serve no at that time.' And at a conference useful purpose press 37 The Statist, September 10, PP* 311-312. during the early stages of the Washington talks, the Chancel lor again declared that he had not changed his mind on the 38 of devaluation.^ question The Statist, September 17, p. 339­ view of this In apparently unyielding stand, the announcement on September 18 that sterling had been de­ valued In terms of the dollar came with dramatic suddenness. The decision to devalue, however, did not come as suddenly. Sir Stafford Crlpps, In his broadcast Informing the British people of this momentous step, explained that the matter had Indeed been carefully studied before his departure for Washington and that The Government decided—and we told our Amer­ican and Canadian colleagues of the decision the first day of our arrival, before starting on any discussions or reduce the dol­ consultations—l§ lar exchange value of sterling.^ 39 Vital Speeches of the Day, Vol. XV, October 1, IW. p- Why, then, the Intransigence of the Chancellor up to the eve of devaluation? It would seem that the announced very of the Government to a downward revision of the opposition value of the pound was intended to hold In check the specu­ lative transactions In sterling which devaluation rumors had set off In the of The Government apparent- spring a ly believed, and wllh good reason, that premature announce hint of the Government’s Intentions would In­ ment or even tensify the speculative influences and contribute even more to the drain on Britain’s gold and dollar reserves. The Immediate Causes of Devaluation Whatever the basic of devaluation causes sterling may have been, and whatever course public and official opinion toward devaluation may have taken, It Is evident that the Immediate occasion for this vital step was the heavy losses In Britain’s gold and dollar reserves, which subject was dealt with In the latter part of the previous chapter. There were three main factors which contributed to the drain on British reserves: (1) the American business recession of (2) an acceleration of the drain of gold to Belgium and Switzerland; and (3) the speculative transactions In sterling. The American recession which began late In and continued through the first half of vas mild In with other American recessions. Yet comparison It pro­ vides a striking example of the apparent sensitivity of and the whole pattern of world trade to foreign economies American business trends. This minor American depression from the United Kingdom reduced not only direct exports to the United States but, what was probably more Important, from the other countries of exports of primary products to the United States. the sterling area Monthly figures In the Trade and Navigation Ac- show that the effects of the American recession on counts not felt until the United Kingdom exports were early par»t 102 of 1949* During the last three months of 1948 the value of United Kingdom exports (including re-exports) to the United States rose steadily, and by January 1949 it reached 6.90 million pounds. In February it underwent a sharp decline to 5*03 million pounds, and by June it had fallen to 3*09 million While the monthly 40 United States Department of Commerce figures show a fall in United States imports from the United Kingdom from $29*68 million in December 1948 to $14.71 million in June 1949 (Survey of Current Business, Vol. 29, September 1949> p. S-22J1 while these figures (when translated into pounds sterling) do not correspond with those given in the Trade and Navigation Accounts, they indicate the same trend that the latter do, i.e., a substantial drop in United Kingdom sales to the United States during the first half of 1949* for the second half of 1948 amounted to 6.13 mil- average lion pounds, it dropped to 4.63 million pounds for the first half of and while the for the first 1949, monthly average quarter of 1949 amounted to 5*83 million pounds. It fell to 3.43 million pounds for the second quarter of 1949* June are shown In Monthly values from July 1948 to 1949 Table 1. of The proportion total United Kingdom exports also the taken by the United States fell sharply during same period. In the fourth quarter of 1948 the value of United Kingdom exports (including re-exports) to the United percent of the total value of States represented 4.25 103 Table 1* Value of United Kingdom Exports (includingre-exports) to the United States and Canada, July 1948-June 1949 (in millions of pounds sterling) Month United States Canada 1948 July 6.43 8.16 August September 5.39 5-93 5.23 6.23 October 6.13 6.39 November 6.44 7.40 December 6.58 5.75 1949 January February March 6.90 5.03 5.55 5.79 5.76 8.09 April May June 3.^5 3.7^ 3.09 6.16 7.66 6.06 United Kingdom exports. In the first quarter of 1949 It represented J.6Q percent of the total, and in the second 41 quarter it fell to 2.29 percent. Source; Accounts Relating to Trade and Navigation of the United Kingdom, London, His Majesty's Stationery Office (various Issues). 41 The Board of Trade Journal, August 27, 1949, p. 385. While United Kingdom exports to the United States were thus declining sharply in the first half of 1949, the same was not true of exports to Canada, the other major dollar country. The Trade and Navigation Accounts show that 1949 in January United Kingdom exports (including re-exports) to Canada were valued at 5*79 million pounds, while in June they amounted to 6.06 million pounds. This, however, does not indicate a rising trend, for since October 1948 exports to Canada had risen and fallen in alternate months, reaching a figure of as much as 8.09 million pounds in March 1949* Month-to-month figures from July 1948 to June 1949 are shown in Table 1. The proportion of United Kingdom exports (includ­ ing re-exports) going to Canada fell from 4.6? percent of the total value In the fourth quarter of 1948 to 4.25 per- of There cent In the first quarter 1949. was, however, 42 of 1 Increase to 4.4? percent In the second quarter 1949­ an 42 The Board of Trade Journal, August 27, 1949, 385* p. indicate a definite fall in The foregoing figures United States purchases of United Kingdom goods during of the business recession in the United the latter part While it is evident that sales to Canada were at States. 105 least maintained, if not slightly increased, during the same period, the dollar earnings accruing to the United Kingdom from these sales were not sufficient to offset the substantial losses sustained in the United States market. Aside from the dollar losses suffered by the United Kingdom, there was an even more marked decline in the dol­ lar earnings of some of the other members of the sterling area as a result of a drop in United States purchases of lack of does not allow for primary The space 43 The Board of Trade Journal, July 16, 19^9, P« 100. a presentation of precise figures of total or primary ex­ ports of each of the sterling countries to the United States the period of the recession. Suffice it to point during out that while the dollar losses of the United Kingdom as a result of the American recession gave enough cause for the added losses of the rest of the sterling area, concern, and they were considerable, gave cause for alarm, since it members the is the dollar earnings of all the of sterling that to make Britain’s reserves. area go up A second factor contributing to the loss of reserves was the accelerated drain of Britain's monetary June and of to Belgium and Switzerland during July gold In June gold and dollar losses to these two countries 1949. totalled 8,409,000 pounds, of which 6,790,000 pounds went to Belgium and 1,619,000 pounds to Switzerland. In July total gold and dollar losses to both countries declined but remained high at 7,299,000 pounds, 4,495,000 pounds going to Belgium and 2,804,000 pounds to Switzerland. Thus, during those two months the United Kingdom was los­ ing gold and dollars to Belgium and Switzerland at an annual rate of 94 This rate million pounds. high of gold losses to both countries be may explained by temporary factors, of ....notably the amount sterling their central banks have derived from the Inflow of British tourists and from the tendency for business con­ cerns and others who normally hold sterling In these countries to run down their balances In order to safeguard themselves against possible devaluation of sterling.^ 44 The Statist, August 13, 1949, p. 191. The third factor which contributed to the decline of the gold and dollar reserves was the speculation In sterling which was set in motion by the talk of devaluation during the spring and summer of 1949* Many traders and had become convinced that devaluation outright speculators of the pound was Inevitable. As a result, foreign Importers of British goods, anticipating a decline In sterling, de­ new and held up payment of sterling Invoices layed purchases 107 This reduced the demand for sterling. At the same time, British importers, expecting a rise in the sterling price of dollars, speeded up purchases and accelerated payment of dollar invoices. This increased the supply of sterling. Thus, the British importers by accelerating dollar payments, as well as the foreign importers by postponing sterling payments, were speculating on a decline in sterling. Out­ right speculators, also anticipating a fall in the dollar value of sterling, converted their pounds into dollars. They purchased dollars at the rate of $4.03 for each pound, dollars hoping to reconvert these into pounds after devalua­ tion (when each dollar would buy more pounds) at a hand­ some profit. Although the Government maintained exchange controls, they contained enough loopholes to allow these speculative activities. As a result of such speculation, the demand for dollars remained at a high level and large 4c, incurred. dollar losses were 45 Ellsworth, P. T. The International Economy (New York: The MacMillan Company, 1 P-~~f4~27 andHarrIs, "Devaluation of the Pound Sterling", Harvard Business S. E. Review, Vol. XXVII, November 1949, pp. TBl-?82. Readjustment of Foreign Currencies 1949 the British Government On September 16, submitted to the International Monetary Fund a proposed change In the to a value of the pound sterling from $4.03 $2.80, reduction of 30*5 percent, in terms of the dollar. With the Fund's approval, this change went into effect on Sunday, September 18, immediately following Sir Stafford Crlpps 1 announcement over the air. Simultaneously, or soon after, a number of countries devalued their currencies to a similar lesser or degree. With the exception of Pakistan, the members of the sterling area also devalued their currencies by 30.5 percent in terms of the dollar. The local currencies of British dependencies, except British Honduras, were de­ valued by 30.5 percent. The Scandinavian countries, Holland, Finland, Argentina, and a few others devalued by 30.5 per­ cent or a slightly smaller proportion. Greece alone de­ preciated her by a greater proportion (33.3 per- currency cent) than sterling. France, Italy, Portugal, Western Germany, Canada, Thailand, and Uruguay, value of their currencies to a lesser extent than reduced the of the pound. Unaffected by this widespread readjustment values were the currencies of the countries foreign exchange and of most of the countries in 46 Latin-America in the Communist area, and the Near East. 46 "Readjustment of Foreign Currency Values , Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 35, October 1949, PP. 1170­"Devaluation Il7l; "a’nd"*Leffingwell, R. C. and European Foreign Affairs, 28, January 1950, p. 203. Vol. Recovery", of In The rapid realignment currency values of the dollar reflected the unbalanced state of trade that existed between the United States and the rest of the world This condition had manifested itself in a world-wide "dol­ lar shortage" or "dollar deficit", which simply meant the inability of most countries to earn enough dollars from their exports to the United States to pay for their neces­ sary dollar purchases. In most of the Western European countries the devaluations expressed a combination of factors quite similar to those which brought about the de­ valuation of sterling. One of the major long-term factors contributing to European devaluation was the distortion between European and United States export prices. The Organization for> European Economic Cooperation in its Interim Report for 1948 noted that "the export prices of many OEEC countries are by no means competitive with those out the for of the United States," and pointed necessity reducing the prices of European exports. The Economic Commission for Europe in its report for 1948 stressed the fact that European export prices had increased more than for the same of goods, and noted United States prices type much that it might become necessary "to bring about a closer realignment between European and American prices The Commission's report further for manufactured goods." noted that currencies in general are overvalued in European relation to the dollar, or rather, since the United States has a large export surplus with the rest of the world and not only with Europe, ...the dollar Is considerably undervalued In relation to all other currencles.*7 These excerpts are quoted In "Readjustment of Foreign Currency Values", clt., p. 1178. loc. Some calculations of comparative export prices as of mld­ suggested that European currencies were overvalued by 15 to 40 percent In terms of the dollar, with most of them between 25 and 30 percent.^ 48 "Readjustment of Foreign Currency Values", loc. cit., p. 1173* As in the case of Britain, of the short-term one factors of Europe's dollar problems was the Impact of the American recession of 1948-1949 upon Europe's export trade. As a result of the recession and falling prices In the United States, there was a sharp reduction of United States In the of Imports from Europe. fourth quarter 1948 Im­ ports from EPP countries amounted to $275 million. By the second quarter of 1949 they had fallen to $l9O million. These Imports represented 14.7 percent of total United States Imports in the fourth quarter of 1948. In the second quarter of 1949 they fell to 11.9 percent. Ibid. The conviction that the high prices of European exports, relative to American prices, were the chief obstacle to expanding trade led to widespread arguments on behalf of a general readjustment of European currencies terms of the dollar. in In the United States, the Ad­ ministration and other sectors of Informed opinion exerted continuing pressure for European devaluation. The United States National Advisory Council on International Monetary and Financial Policies reported in July 1949 that "in some cases the revaluation of currencies constitute may an im­ portant means of bringing about the desired expansion of exports to the dollar area....” Early in September both the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank came out in favor of a revision of European Currencies. The IMP in its report for 1948-49 noted that "where a price reduction...is necessary to expand exports, it would in many cases seem possible only through an adjustment of the exchange And Mr. Eugene Black, the president of 50 in Excerpts quoted "Readjustment of Foreign Cur­rency Values", loc. cit., p. 1178. the International Bank, in a speech to the governors of the stated that if the European countries hoped to solve Bank their dollar problem there must be established a system of exchange will assist the dollar deficit rates which countries to in world markets, incentive to ex- compete effectively will furnish an porters increase their sales in the dollar to area and will sl encourage importers to buy. Quoted in The Statist, September 17, 1949, p. 559 With the United States Government and such influ­ ential international bodies as the Fund and the Bank urging a realignment of exchange rates, a general devaluation be­ came virtually inevitable and only a matter of time. Most of the Western European countries, being in the same pre­ dicament as Britain, were only waiting for the latter "to take the lead and to give a touch of respectability to devaluation. When the pound fell, the other currencies 32 Lefflngwell, loc. cit., p. 204. went tumbling after. Chapter IV THE IMMEDIATE EFFECTS OF DEVALUATION The decision of the British Government to devalue the pound was obviously based on the belief that lower dollar prices for British goods would increase volumethe to of exports dollar countries in a large enough proportion to produce greater dollar returns. Furthermore, it was be­ lieved that with the value of the United States dollar re- could undersell maining unchanged, British goods many United States goods in third markets and thus the volume and value (in terms of dollars) of total British exports would also be increased. Britain's competitive position was also expected to improve, but to a lesser degree, vis-a-vis countries devaluing their currencies by a smaller percentage than sterling. In other words, the Government of an overall elastic demand for assumed the presence British exports. The devaluation of sterling reflected the failure drive and the severe import re- of the vigorous export strictions as the best possible means of balancing Britain's current transactions with the dollar area, the chief sore spot in the general balance of payments. Moreover, it re- more on price and profit incentives to flected a desire rely 113 to British manufacturers and exporters in order to achieve the needed export increase. Although aware of the tempor­ ary nature of any benefits stemming from devaluation, British officials apparently were confident that exports, especially dollar exports, could be expanded sufficiently to balance Britain's external payments, especially dollar payments, before sterling prices would rise. When carefully analyzed, however, the actual pros­ pects for expansion of British exports were not so bright. It would not be enough for the volume of dollar exports merely to rise. It would have to rise by a much greater proportion than the percentage drop in the dollar value of sterling. For example, if the sterling prices of British remained unchanged and their dollar prices fell exports hy 30.5 percent (the full extent of devaluation), the volume of dollar exports would have to increase by about 43 percent in order just to obtain the pre-devaluation dollar receipts. If dollar earnings were to increase the above the pre-devaluation level, volume of dollar ex- would have to increase by more than 43 percent. If, ports however, sterling prices should rise, the additional volume of exports required would be smaller, depending on the magnitude of the price rise; but a smaller volume at more higher sterling prices would be that much difficult to sell than the larger volume at unchanged sterling 1 prices. Assuming an elastic demand for British goods. 1 Harris, S. E. flDevaluation of the Pound Sterling", Harvard Business Review, Vol. XXVII, November 1949, p. 783 ; and Ellsworth, P. T. The International Economy (New York: The MacMillan Company 7 1950), p. ?43. the larger volume seemed easier to attain, and the chief problem would be to delay the rise in sterling prices. United Kingdom Merchandise Trade in the First Year After Devaluation There are no official figures indicating changes in the volume of United Kingdom trade with individual countries. It is, therefore, difficult to determine con­ clusively whether the volume of United Kingdom trade with the United States, Canada, or any other country in the dollar area moved in the required direction and in the re­ quired proportion to produce greater dollar yields follow­ ing the devaluation of sterling. But, changes in the volume of trade with the dollar countries are not as im­ as value of such portant changes in the trade, figures for which are readily available. The latter changes will determine whether dollar receipts increased following de­ valuation, and to the extent that they Increased, it may be assumed that the volume of dollar trade must have changed in the required direction and proportion to produce the increase. in Monthly figures the Trade and Navigation Accounts of the United Kingdom indicate a definite increase in the value of United Kingdom exports to the United States (in terms of in the first sterling) year after devaluation (see Chart l). In September 1949 such exports amounted to 4.47 million pounds. By September 1950 they had risen to 12.88 million pounds, an increase of 188 percent. During the same period the wholesale price index of the United = rose from 212 to Kingdom steadily 250 percent (1937100), an increase of 18 percent. This was an encouraging sign, since exports might be expected to continue to rise until prices increased by about 45 percent. In the case of United Kingdom imports from the United States, the trend was not as encouraging. Chart 1 to such shows that from September July 1950 Imports underwent a considerable decline (in terms of sterling). from the United States In September imports were valued at 16.29 million pounds. By July 1950 they had fal­ 10.65 million pounds, a drop of 35 percent. In the len to latter month, the United Kingdom actually had an export surplus in its trade with the United States. As shown by the Chart, however, imports from the United States increased sharply after July and reached 18.30 million pounds in 117 from Imports and to Exports Kingdom United of Value 1. Chart Price 'i 1950 Wholesale i the and i Sterling July Pounds in States United the Kingdom, i United i the of i Index 118 September 1950. Thus, from September to September, Imports actually Increased by 12 percent. Calculated on a quarter­ ly basis, imports decreased from a monthly average of 17.19 million pounds in the third quarter of to a monthly average of 14.61 million pounds in the third quarter of 1950, a fall of only 15 percent. p 2 Calculated from figures in Accounts Relating to Trade and Navigation of the United Kingdom^tvarious Issues The foregoing figures may be taken as an indication of that by September 1950 the value United Kingdom exports to the United States, in terms of sterling, was definitely increasing and apparently fulfilling expectations. The trend in the value of imports from the United States, also in terms of sterling, however, is difficult to analyze. the value of to have By one calculation, imports appears risen, but only by a very slight percentage. By another calculation, it appears to have fallen, but also by a very slight percentage. At any rate, imports, in terms of ster­ seem to have contributed little to correct the United ling, Kingdom's trade balance with the United States. This is that no surprise. It was expected an adjustment should be made mainly on the side of exports. With imports already 119 cut to foodstuffs and materials essential to the post-war reconversion it was believed that the higher program, sterling prices British dollar imports resulting from of devaluation would fail to discourage such imports enough to reduce their volume to an appreciable extent. What is volume of at more important, a virtually unchanged imports higher prices would be expected to result in a considerably increased import bill, in terms of sterling. The import figures quoted above would thus seem to surpass pre-devalua tion expectations concerning imports from the United States In terms of dollars the picture is somewhat dif­ ferent. Figures in the Survey of Current Business also indicate a rising trend in the value of United Kingdom ex- to the United States (in terms of dollars) in the ports first year following devaluation (see Chart 2), In Septem­ to States amounted ber 1949 exports the United to $20,62 million. By September 1959 they had risen to $51.46 mil­ lion, an Increase of 52 percent. This increase was consid­ erably under the percentage rise in the sterling value of smaller increase in the dollar value was to exports, but a as a result of the new relative values of be expected the two currencies. A further increase in the dollar value of exports to the United States might be expected as long as wholesale prices in the United Kingdom did not rise by 45 percent. 120 1950 Imports Wholesale to ­ and 1949-September Exports the and Kingdom Dollars July Kingdom, United in of States United Value United the of 11l 2. the IndexChart from United Kingdom imports from the United States during the same period show no clear trend (see Chart 2). As in the case of the dollar value of such sterling value, imports fell to from $52.37 million in September 1949 $24.05 million in July 1950, a drop of 54 percent. In June and July the United Kingdom had an export surplus with the United States in terras of dollars. There was, however, a sharp increase in imports from the United States after July, and by Septem­ ber 1950 they had risen to $59*54 million, an increase of 147 percent from July to September of 195° and an increase of 14 percent from September 1949 to September 1950. Figured on a quarterly basis, however, imports from the United States fell from a monthly average of $51.96 million in the third quarter of 1949 to a monthly average of $41.72 million in the third quarter of 1950> a drop of 20 percent.^ 3 Calculated from figures In Survey of Current Business (various issues). Thus, in terms of dollars as in terms of sterling. United Kingdom imports from the United States tended to decrease, at least until July 1950* It should, however, be noted that in terms of dollars imports declined by a slightly larger percentage than in terms of sterling. As in the case of exports, this was to be expected because of the changed values of the two currencies. relative 122 Aside from the new exchange rate, other factors may have contributed to the discrepancy between the dollar and values and sterling of exports imports. The two sets of are taken from two different one figures sources, British, the other American. It is quite possible that the figures in one source are based on f.o.b. values, while those in the other source are based on C.i.f. values. The question of timing is also important. The merchandise exported or imported by the United Kingdom in one month not be the may same merchandise imported or exported by the United States in that month. The dollar figures are, of course, the important ones in determining whether Britain’s dollar earnings Increased following devaluation. With the exception of June and July of 1950, the dollar figures give little indication of a definite narrowing of the trade gap between the United Kingdom and the United States in the year following deval­ uation. In September the United Kingdom's trade deficit with the United States amounted to $31.75 million. In September 1950 it amounted to $28.08 million, a reduction of only 11.6 percent. United Kingdom trade with Canada appears to have been more favorably affected than trade with the United States. The Trade and Navigation Accounts show a definite rise in the value of United Kingdom exports to Canada (in 123 terms of sterling) during the year after devaluation (see Chart 3)* From 5*50 million pounds In September 1949 such to exports rose 10.31 million pounds In September 1950, an Increase of 87 percent. Since during the same period wholesale prices in the United Kingdom had risen by only 18 percent, a further Increase In exports to Canada might be expected. Imports from Canada underwent a slight downward trend (in terms of sterling) In the first twelve months after devaluation. They fell from 16.28 million pounds In September 1949 to 11.77 million pounds In September 1950, a drop of 27.7 percent. The downward trend, as shown In Chert 3, actually began In July 1949* In which month Im­ ports from Canada were valued at 22.36 million pounds. Thus, from July 1949 to September 1950 these Imports de­ creased by 47.4 percent. Of more Importance are the dollar figures for United Kingdom trade with Canada. Data taken from the Canadian Statistical Review Indicate, as would be expected, a smal­ to ler Increase in United Kingdom exports Canada In terms than In of Chart From of dollars terms sterling (see 4). million In September 1949 such exports rose to $21.94 Increase of $36.21 million In September 1950, an 65 per­ cent, as compared with 87 percent In terms of sterling. 124 I Imports Price 1950 i to ­ and Wholesale the Exports i and July Kingdom SterlingKingdom, i United of Pounds United . Value in the of Canada 3* i Index from Chart Canada Kingdom, from Imports and to Exports Kingdom United of Value 4. Chart United the of Index Price Wholesale the and Dollars In 1 1 1 1 1 1950 1 1 9-September 1 194 1 July 1 1 1 1 Additional data, however, Indicate, as would also be ex­ pected, a greater fall in United Kingdom imports from Canada in terms of dollars than in terms of sterling. In such amounted to million. September 1949 imports $56.95 By September 1950 they had fallen to $50.44 million, a drop of in terms of 46.6 percent, as compared with 27*7 percent sterling. The downward trend in imports, according to In which month Chart 4, had really begun in July 1949, they amounted to $70.55 million. Thus, from July 1949 to from Canada September 1950, imports fell by 56.9 percent, as compared with 47.4 percent in terms of sterling. In terms of dollars the United Kingdom achieved an export surplus with Canada in March, April, and September of 1950 (see Chart 4). In terms of sterling it failed to achieve an ex­ port surplus in any of the twelve months following devaluation (see Chart 5). In terms of both dollars and sterling, but more so in terms of dollars, it Is clear that the United Kingdom 1 s trade deficit with Canada was reduced considerably in the first after devaluation. Whereas there was an year import surplus of $55*01 million with Canada in September achieved 1949, an export surplus of $5*77 million was in September 1950. The foregoing figures for United Kingdom trade with Canada indicate that in terms of dollars exports to Canada increased by a greater percentage than exports to the United States and that Imports from Canada declined by a greater percentage than Imports from the United States. These trends did not follow pre-devaluation expectations. Since Canada had devalued her dollar by 9»1 percent while the United States dollar remained stable, the latter had ap­ preciated In value, vls-a-vls sterling, by a greater per­ centage than the former. It had, therefore, been expected that United Kingdom exports to the United States should in­ crease In greater proportion than exports to Canada and that United Kingdom Imports from the United States should fall in greater proportion than Imports from Canada. It is not pertinent to this study to determine why United trade with the United States and Canada should Kingdom have followed a pattern opposite to the one expected. The various factors responsible for such an outcome would re- and the quire lengthy analysis and discussion, answer might still be uncertain. The chief purpose here Is to determine the of the In- whether dollar earnings United Kingdom to what extent. creased following devaluation, and. If so, The dollar value of United Kingdom exports to both totalled $42.56 million the United States and Canada In 1949. In the same month, the dollar value of September United Kingdom imports from these two countries totalled $109.52 million, making for a trade deficit of $66.76 mil- dollar countries. lion with the two major In September 128 1950 exports to the United States and Canada had risen to $67.67 million, while imports from them had declined to $89.98 million, making for a trade deficit of $22.31 million. These figures represent a reduction of 66.6 percent in the United Kingdom's trade deficit with the United States and Canada and a net gain of $44.45 million in its dollar earn­ ings from these two countries during the first year after devaluation. Calculated on a quarterly basis. United King­ dom exports to both countries amounted to a monthly average of $43.11 million in the third quarter of 1949* In the same quarter, imports amounted to a monthly average of $115.42 mil lion, resulting in a trade deficit of $72.31 million with dollar countries. In the of both major third quarter 1950 exports to the United States and Canada rose to a monthly of $65.81 million, while Imports from them fell to average a monthly average of $77*77 million, resulting in a trade deficit of only $11.96 million. These figures represent a reduction of 85.5 percent in the United Kingdom's trade deficit with the two chief countries of the dollar area and a of million in its from them net gain $60.35 dollar earnings from the third quarter of 1949 (immediately prior to deval­ uation) to the third quarter of 1950 (a year after devalu­ ation) Calculated from figures in Survey of Current Business and Canadian Statistical Review, Vol. December 1950# p. 106. (various issues) XXV, To summarize the trends In United Kingdom trade with the United States and Canada In the year after devalua­ tion; It Is evident from the above figures that the United Kingdom's dollar earnings Increased considerably as a re­ sult of Its merchandise trade with these two countries, and a although deficit remained. It had been substantially re­ duced by September 1950. Furthermore, it must be remem­ bered that during the same time wholesale prices in the United Kingdom Increased by only 18 percent. This Indicated that, assuming the applicability of a purchasing power par­ ity analysis to the situation, the same favorable trends In trade with the two major dollar countries should continue, although at a decreasing rate, as long as prices did not rise by 43 percent. trade with the whole dollar area also United Kingdom Improved following devaluation. No summarized figures are available for such trade on a monthly basts. However, half- summaries show a substantial reduction. In terms of year dollars, in the United Kingdom’s trade deficit with the whole dollar In the second half of 1949 area during 1930* United Kingdom exports and re-exports (f.0.b.) to the dollar amounted to $313 million, while Imports (f.0.b.) from the dollar area amounted to $772 million, making for a trade area deficit of $459 million. J In the second half of 1950 exports 3 Cmd. 8065, United Kingdom Balance of Payments to 1950 (London: His Majesty 1 s Stationery office, October TSSGT,' P-25. and re-exports (f.0.b.) to the dollar area rose to $512 mil­ lion, while imports (f.0.b.) from the dollar area declined in a trade to $633 million, resulting deficit of $l2l million/" a reduction These of figures represent 73*6 6 Britain f s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093 (British Information Services, october 1931)> p. ?• percent in the United Kingdom f s trade deficit with the whole dollar area and a net gain of $358 million in its total dol­ merchandise in lar earnings (from trade) one year. At this point it would be worthwhile, or at least interesting, to note the trend in United Kingdom trade with two non-dollar countries during the first year after devaluation. Chart 5 shows that, except for small fluctu­ ations from month to month. United Kingdom exports to and imports from India, in terms of sterling, remained virtually unchanged from September 1949 to September 1950. This is as it should have been, for with India devaluing her currency as in terms in the same proportion sterling (30.5 percent) r in lndia Kingdom, ¦ r United 1 the Imports 1 of and 1950 to Index 1 1 Exports Price 1 Kingdom Wholesale July the United and of Value Sterling 5­ Pounds Chart of the dollar, its value had remained stable vls-a-vls and sterling, the United Kingdom’s competitive position as had against India’s remained unchanged. Nobody had ex­ pected the pattern of United Kingdom trade with India to be affected substantially as a result of the devaluation. Trade with Pakistan, however, underwent some changes, but not in the It must be remembered that way expected. Pakistan was the only member of the sterling area that maintained the value of its when the pound fell. currency It had, therefore, appreciated, vis-a-vis sterling, in the same proportion as the United States dollar. Thus, it would seem that United Kingdom exports to and Imports from Pakistan, should have moved in the same direction in terms of sterling, and proportion as exports to and imports from the United States, in terms of sterling. Exports to Pakistan, as shown in Chart 6, increased in the first year after devalua­ tion. From 1.69 million pounds in September 1949 they rose to 3,26 million pounds in September 1950, an increase of 95 percent. This was considerably below the increase of 188 to the United States the same percent in exports during from Pakistan increased from 0.8l period. Imports million pounds in September 1949 to 1.?3 million pounds in September 1950, a rise of 120 percent. In the same period. United Kingdom Imports from the United States rose by only 12 o Pakistan Kingdom, from United Imports the of 1950 and Index . to r Price Exports Kingdom Wholesale July the United and of Sterling Value 6. Pounds Chart in rs.. percent. When calculated on a the rise quarterly basis, in imports from Pakistan was not as great. Prom a monthly average of 0.91 million pounds in the third quarter of of they rose to a monthly average 1.47 million pounds in the third quarter of 195°* a rise of 61 percent.’ The 7 Calculated from figures In Accounts Relating to and of the Trade Navigation United KTngdoirP(Various issues) quarterly calculations for imports from the United States, however, revealed that In the same period such Imports fell the from by 15 percent. Since figures for Imports Pakistan are in pounds sterling, they Indicate an Inelastic demand for Pakistan goods. Analyzing the reasons for the failure of United Kingdom trade with Pakistan to follow trends of its trade with the United States is similar to those also beyond the scope of this study. The foregoing figures merely point out how unreliable expectations concerning the effects of devaluation can be. With respect to the trend of total United Kingdom exports and Imports following devaluation, the monthly figures in the Trade and Navigation Accounts reveal that in terms moved somewhat total exports, of sterling, ac- to i.e., they increased. Chart 7 cording expectations, a slight increase in the sterling value of total indicates in Imports and Exports Kingdom United Total of Value 7* Chart 135 Kingdom, United the of 1950 Index Price 'Wholesale July the and Stealing Pounds 136 exports daring the year after devaluation. From 145.56 million pounds in September 1949 exports rose to 180.53 mil­ lion pounds in September 1930, an increase of 24 percent. Assuming unchanging sterling prices, it was necessary that the sterling value of exports increase by more than 43 percent in order for their dollar value to increase above the pre-devaluation level. As will be shown below, the dollar value decreased instead of Increasing in the year after devaluation. The sterling value of total Imports increased as expected. Prom 181.65 million pounds in September 1949 they increased to 193-92 million pounds in September 1950> a rise of 7 percent. A rise of 24 percent in the sterling value of total for the mentioned above, but reason exports was discouraging wholesale prices did not rise by 43 a as long as percent, further increase in exports might be expected. Gn the side of imports the only encouraging aspect, for its pos­ sible effect on the balance of payments, was the fact that to after July 1950 total imports began decline sharply. of did not the The sterling value imports fall below Septem­ ber 1949 value of the twelve months following devalua­ in any to tion. But this was only according expectations. Imports, to in terms of sterling, were not expected help in correcting the balance-of-payments disequilibrium. Their essential nature Indicated that at best they could only be held to a minimum Increase. When viewed In terms of sterling, the total trade position of the United Kingdom shows no definite Improve­ ment following devaluation. A glimpse at Chart 7 will reveal that, except In September 1950, the gap between total exports and imports failed to narrow appreciably dur­ ing the first year after devaluation. In September 1949 the United Kingdom had an Import surplus of 56.09 million pounds. In September 1950 the Import surplus amounted to 15*59 million pounds. In terms of dollars the situation was even more distressing. There are no monthly figures on the dollar value of total United Kingdom exports and Imports; however, the February 1951 Issue of International Financial Statis­ tics figures on the dollar value of United Kingdom gives and for one whole after devaluation exports Imports year for whole year compared with figures one preceding devalua- For the twelve months prior to devaluation (October tion. 1948-September 1949) United Kingdom exports (f.0.b.) the months totalled $7,285 million. For twelve following devaluation (October 1949-September 1950) they totalled $5,915 million, a decline of 17*4 percent. United Kingdom Imports (c.1.f.) In the twelve months before devaluation amounted to $8,926 million, while In the twelve months after 138 devaluation they fell to $7,036 million, a drop of 21.2 Q percent. Thus, In terms of dollars and calculated on 8 International Financial Statistics, Vol. IV, Febru­ary 1951> PP* xx-xxi. whole-year basis, the total exports of the United Kingdom In failed to increase, as expected, following devaluation. fact, they decreased noticeably. Total imports also de­ creased, but only moderately. As a result, the Import sur­ plus of the United Kingdom was not appreciably reduced. For the twelve months preceding devaluation the import surplus amounted to $1,64l million. For the twelve months follow­ ing devaluation it amounted to $1,121 million, a reduction of 51.7 Speaking in terms of dollars, devaluation. 9 Calculated from figures In Ibid. to have been unsuccessful in achieving therefore, appears its primary objective; a substantial expansion of United Kingdom exports. The limited reduction in the import sur­ was possible only because imports declined by a greaterplus than exports. percentage Some idea of the sacrifice involved in attaining in the this limited Improvement trade balance can be got 139 from a look at the trend followed by the United Kingdom terms of trade during the year after devaluation. Chart 8 shows that export prices, as expected, rose slightly following devaluation. From 113 percent (1947=100) in September 1949 the export price index rose to 121 percent in September 1950* an increase of 7 percent. Import prices, as expected, also increased noticeably. From 110 percent (1947=100) in September 1949 the import price index climbed to 137 per­ cent in September 1950, an increase of 24 percent. With import prices rising in greater proportion than export prices, the result was a deterioration of the terms of trade against the United Kingdom. From 102.8 percent (1947=100) in September 1949 the terms of trade index fell steadily (see Chart 8) to 88.3 percent in September 1950, a drop of 14.1 percent. This is a relatively small decline and does not represent a serious deterioration of the terms of trade. The United Kingdom appears to have had very limited success in its merchandise trade during the twelve months follow- devaluation. But the sacrifice incurred also appears ing to have been limited. in the Balance of Improvement Payments Despite the inability of the United Kingdom to make reduction in its visible trade deficit, it a significant 1949-September July Kingdom, United the of Trade of Terms 8. Chart 141 succeeded In attaining a considerable overall surplus in its balance of payments in 1950* This was made possible by the substantial improvement in the invisible trade balance during that year. Although the United Kingdom had an overall surplus of 16 million pounds in the first half of 1949, it sus-1 tained an overall deficit of 54 million pounds in the second half of that year. This reversal was brought about by an increase in the visible trade deficit from 43 to 104 million pounds and a decrease in the invisible trade sur­ plus from 59 to 5° million pounds over the same period. Thus, for the whole of 1949 there was an overall balance- of-payments deficit of 38 million pounds, made up of a visible trade deficit of 147 million pounds and an invisible lo trade surplus of 109 million pounds.' ' In the first half 10 Cmd. 8063, p. 7« The latest balance-of-payments figures for* give an overall surplus of 20 million made of a visible trade deficit of 152 million pounds, up pounds and an invisible trade surplus of 172 million pounds (British Record (British Information Services), November 15, 1951> P« l)• of of 1950 the United Kingdom achieved an overall surplus 42 million pounds and in the second half of that year one overall of 179 million pounds, resulting in an surplus of whole This 221 million pounds for the year. substantial 142 surplus was facilitated by an Increase in the invisible trade surplus to 380 million pounds end achieved despite an increase in the visible trade deficit to 159 million pounds in 1950. The most important items in the increased in­ 11 Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, p. 5. visible earnings were shipping and income from interest, and dividends. net profits, In 1949 shipping receipts amounted to 88 million pounds and net earnings fr*om inter- and amounted to 62 est, profits, dividends million pounds.^ 12 Cmd. 8065, p. 7. In 1950 shipping receipts netted 115 million pounds, and earnings from Interest, profits, and dividends netted 123 13 J million pounds. 13 Britain! s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, P* 5. the United Kingdom attained an overall sur- Although plus in its general balance of payments in 1950, a deficit in Its current transactions with the dollar ares remained. 143 However, this deficit, like the dollar trade deficit, was substantially reduced during 1950* In the second half of 1949 the deficit in current transactions with the dollar area amounted to 160 million pounds ($538 million), which, together with the deficit of 142 million pounds ($571 mil­ -14 lion) sustained in the first half of the same year, re­ 14 The dollar figure with the larger smaller sterling figure is due to the fact that the dollar equivalent of the sterling figure for the first half of 1949 is calculated at the old exchange rate of $4.03=1 pound; whereas, the dol­lar equivalent of the sterling figure for the second half of 1949 is calculated partly (up to the time of devaluation in September) at the old rate of $4.03=1 pound and partly (after devaluation) at the new rate of $2,80=1 pound. suited in a dollar deficit of 302 million pounds ($1,109 million) for the whole of 1949. This dollar deficit was made up of a visible trade deficit of 251 million pounds ($903 million) and an invisible tr*ade deficit of 51 million pounds ($206 million). 15 In 1950 the United Kingdom's deficit 15 Cmd. 8065, p. 25* with the dollar area was reduced to 107 million pounds ($299 million), consisting of a visible trade deficit of 113 mil­ lion pounds ($314 million) and an invisible trade surplus 144 of 6 million pounds ($l5 million). J Thus, a reduction of 16 Britain's Balance of Payments Position, ID 1095, pp. 6-7. 64.6 percent in terms of sterling and of 7? percent in terms of dollars was made in the United Kingdom's dollar deficit during 1950. The total net gold and dollar deficit of the whole sterling area, which had persisted since the war, was, un­ like the United Kingdom's own dollar deficit, turned into a substantial surplus in 1950-In the second half of the sterling area deficit amounted to $570 million, which, added to the deficit of $962 million in the first half of resulted in a net and dollar deficit of that year, gold million for the whole of The $1,351 greater part of this deficit, $1,196 million, was financed by E. R. P. funds. Of the remainder, $l6B million was financed by credits and $167 million by drawings on the gold and dollar 17 reserves of the sterling area. In 1950 a net gold and 17 Cmd. 8065, p. 27. dollar surplus of SBOS million was achieved by the sterling area. This surplus, together with Marshall Aid amounting to $762 million and credits amounting to $45 million, brought about an addition of $1,612 million to the gold and dollar reserves In 1950. As a result of this favor­ able turn, the reserves, which amounted to $1,688 million at the end of rose substantially to $3,300 million 1950.^ the end of by 18 Britain 1 s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, 8. p. This sharp Increase in the sterling area's gold and dollar reserves represents the most Important post-devalua­ tion development. It must be remembered that the heavy losses of reserves In the spring and summer of 1949 was the chief immediate cause of sterling devaluation, and that on the day of devaluation the reserves were down to $1,340 million. Thus, by the end of 1950 the sterling area's gold and dol­ lar holdings had Increased by 95 percent over the holdings at the end of 1949 and by 146 percent over the holdings on the day when devaluation went Into effect. Furthermore, the figure of $3,300 million at the end of 1950 was the highest since the war. Such a marked improvement in the reserve position In little more than a year after devaluation must 146 be regarded as a highly creditable and gratifying achieve­ ment . Evaluation It may be well to summarize the trends followed by United Kingdom merchandise trade In the year after devalua­ tion. United Kingdom exports to the United States and Canada (in terms of dollars) appear to have moved accord­ ing to pre-devaluation expectations, 1.e., they Increased substantially. United Kingdom imports from these two countries decreased slightly. The trends were more favor­ able with respect to Canada than with respect to the United States, 1.e., exports to Canada Increased In greater pro­portion than exports to the United States and Imports from Canada decreased in greater proportion than Imports from the United States. A.S a result of these trends the United Kingdom's trade deficit with Canada was considerably reduced and a surplus achieved in September 1950, while the trade with the United States failed to close appreciably. gap The United Kingdom's trade deficit with the two major dol­ lar countries taken together, while not eliminated, was sub­ stantially reduced In the first year following devaluation. The trade deficit with the whole dollar area was also considerably reduced but not abolished. One encouraging aspect in the situation was the fact that during the same in the period wholesale prices United Kingdom rose by only 18 percent. As long as such prices would not rise by 43 percent, a continuation of the favorable trends in the United Kingdom's dollar trade, especially the rise in ex­ ports, might be expected. The total merchandise trade of the United Kingdom (in terms of dollars) apparently failed to improve in the following devaluation. Total United year Kingdom exports, instead of rising as expected, underwent a noticeable decline, while total Imports decreased somewhat and in greater proportion than total exports. As a result, the total trade deficit of the United Kingdom was not ap­ preciably reduced. The terms of trade, as expected, moved in the against the United Kingdom year after devaluation, but to a small extent. very Despite the inability of the United Kingdom notably to reduce its visible trade deficit following devaluation, it was able to increase its invisible trade surplus sub­ stantially and, as a result, to obtain an overall balance- of-payments surplus of 221 million pounds in 1950. But for the considerable increase in invisible earnings, this surplus would not, of course, have been possible. The United Kingdom's deficit in current transactions with the dollar area continued, although it was substantially re- and duced during 1950. But the net gold dollar deficit of 148 of the whole sterling area became a surplus of SBOS million In 1950. As a result, the gold and dollar reserves of the sterling area rose to their post-war peak of $3,300 million. Thus, the most notable post-devaluation improve­ ments to in Britain’s balance-of-payments position appear have been the large surplus attained in the invisible balance of the United Kingdom and the substantial Increase in the gold and dollar holdings of the whole sterling area. The latter development was perhaps the more important one. It demonstrated that devaluation, however little it may have accomplished toward a permanent solution of the British problem, was at least successful as a short-term corrective measure. It appears to have solved the immediate problem of the sterling area’s diminishing reserves. It would be a serious mistake to assume that the in the United Kingdom's merchandise limited improvements trade with the dollar countries and the notable improve- in Britain's balance-of-payments position were made ments solely because of sterling devaluation. Certainly, the devaluation played a large part in bringing about these but its effectiveness would be overestimated improvements, if it were given sole credit for the favorable changes. be too soon to assess all the factors af- Although it may fecting British trade and Britain's balance of payments 149 following devaluation and to determine precisely the degree of their Influence, it Is clear that certain factors other than devaluation were Important In Britain’s Improved posi­ tion. One of the chief reasons for the Increase In United Kingdom exports to the United States appears to have been the change in business conditions in the latter country. Following the end of the recession about the middle of 1949* United States imports Increased as business condi­ tions Improved in the second half of 1949 and the first half of 1950* The relative importance of this factor in the expansion of United Kingdom dollar exports would be difficult if not Impossible to gauge. Mr. J. J. Polak of the International Monetary Fund in a recent - pr* e 19 Polak, J. J. ’’Contribution of the-September Devaluations to the Solution of Europe's Dollar Problem”, Staff Papers (international Monetary Fund), Vol. 11, 8-11. September 1951* PP« 1-32. See pp. sents some useful data showing the effect of improved business conditions in the United States on European exports to He (including United Kingdom exports) that country. finds that the value of United States imports from European countries rose parallel with a sharp rise in United States the industrial production from third quarter of 1949 to the second quarter of 1950. The same parallelism is implied with respect to United States imports from the United Kingdom. Another factor contributing to the rise in United Kingdom dollar exports following devaluation appears to have been the export drive on dollar markets promoted by the British Government. It Is possible that this drive, started long before devaluation, may not have begun to bear fruit until 1950. The importance of this factor is 20 also difficult to assess. 20 Polak, loc. clt., p. 12. The increase in business activity in the United States in the latter part of also appears to have affected favorably the exports of the whole sterling area to the United States. This expansion of exports to dollar markets, coupled with a fall in the dollar imports of the sterling contributed greatly to the reduction of the area, area’s net gold and dollar deficit in the second half of 21 One factor which had an immediate (i.e. short­ 21 The Economist, January 7, 1950, p. 35* 151 term) effect on the sterling area's dollar balance was the reversal of the speculative operations which had taken place in anticipation of sterling devaluation. In the few months prior to devaluation these speculative influences had acted to increase the dollar deficit of the sterling area and, consequently, to accelerate the drain on the gold and dollar reserves. Conversely, their reversal in the first few months after devaluation acted to reduce the dollar deficit and, thus, to replenish the reserves.^ 22 The Economist, January 7, 1950, p. 35* One other factor which appears to have contributed heavily to the improvement of Britain’s balance-of-payments position in 1950 must be mentioned. The outbreak of the Korean war in June 1950 was followed, in the second half of 1950, by a sharp rise in United States imports from all countries. This import upsurge was related primarily to the rearmament program and the stockpiling of strategic materials.^3 25 Polak, Idc> clt., p. 12. Included in this general import rise were substantial in­ creases in United States imports from the United Kingdom 152 and the rest of the sterling area. The monthly average of United States Imports from the United Kingdom rose from $21.1 million in the first half of 1950 to $35*2 million in the second half of that year (This, however, was more than the rise offset by sharp in United Kingdom imports from the United States beginning in July 1950). United States im­ ports from the rest of the sterling area rose from a month­ ly average of $93-5 million in the first half of 1950 to a monthly of $117*7 million in the second half of average that The increase in imports from the year. greatest sterling area was in rubber and rubber articles. The month ly average of such imports more than doubled from the first 24 to the second half of 1950. Largely as a result of this 24 Sterling Area Facts and Figures, ID 1122 (British Information"Services7-January-1’555)’, p." 11. increase in United States purchases of sterling area goods, the sterling area's dollar balance rose from a surplus of million in the first half of 1950 to a surplus of $585 $220 25 million in the second half of that year, which of course 25 Britain's Balance of Payments Position, ID 1095, 7• p. contributed in no small measure to the substantial Increase in the gold and dollar reserves in 1950. Chapter V THE 1951 CRISIS In 1951 Britain’s balance-of-payments position deteriorated once more. The favorable effects of the de­ valuation were at an end, and Britain's balance on cur­ rent account was again in deficit. The limited improve­ ment which was made in Britain's merchandise trade balance following devaluation began to disappear toward the end of 1950, and by the third quarter of 1951 the trade deficit had increased by tremendous proportions. The steady rise In the value of total United King­ dom exports (in terms of sterling), which characterized the first after devaluation, was continued in the fourth year quarter of 1950 and over into 1951; however, during the same period the value of total United Kingdom imports (in terms of sterling) also increased steadily, hut at a much faster rate than the value of total exports. The result, of course, was a steady widening of the trade gap. The latest monthly figures show that by the third quarter of 1951 United Kingdom exports and re-exports (f.0.b.) had risen to a monthly average of 250 million pounds. This represents an increase of 27 percent over September 1950. During the same period United Kingdom imports (c.i.f.) 154 rose to a monthly average of 555 million pounds, represent­ ing an Increase of 85 percent over September 1950. As a result, the apparent trade increased to a monthly 1 deficit is greater than the real The apparent deficit, because It Ts based on c.i.f. import figures which include freight and insurance costs. of 125 million pounds in the third quarter of 1951­ average This indicates an increase of 853 percent over September 1950 and of 551 percent over the monthly average of 29 mil­ -2 lion pounds for the year 1950-It is obvious that the 2 British Record (British Information Services), November 257 P • "4". for this unfavorable turn in the trade balance was reason not a failure to expand exports (they continued to rise), but the more rapid increase in imports. The most recent trade figures show that for the whole 1951 the apparent trade deficit of the United year Kingdom amounted to 1,210 million pounds. The worsening of Britain's trade position in 1951 can be more readily ap­ preciated if one notes that for the whole of 1950 the apparent trade deficit was only 352 million pounds. The 156 peal trade deficit (based on an f.o.b. valuation of imports) 3 would, of course, be less but still very large. The real 3 British Record, January 22, 1952, p. 4. trade deficit figure for the whole year 1951 is not yet available. For the first half of that year, however, the 4 real deficit amounted to 338 million pounds. At o that rate. 4 British Record, October 31, 1931# p. 1* the whole-year figure would amount to 676 million pounds. This contrasts sharply with the trade deficit of 159 mil­ lion pounds in 1950­ There are no figures for the United Kingdom’s in­ visible trade for the whole year 1951* But, in the first half of that there was an invisible trade surplus of year 216 million at which rate the whole-year surplus 5 Ibid. should be 432 million pounds. This would be an increase of 52 million pounds over the invisible trade surplus for 1950. Thus, for the first half of 1951 the overall balance 157 g 1 of-payments deficit amounted to 122 million pounds, or 6 British Record, October 31, 1951, P« 1* an annual rate of 244 million pounds. This represents a tremendous deterioration in Britain! s overall balance-of payments position over 1950# when the United Kingdom en­ joyed an overall surplus of 221 million pounds. In the first half of 1951 the United Kingdom's cur­ rent account with the dollar area was in deficit to the amount of 109 million pounds ($305 million), making for an 7 Britain's Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093 (British Informatfon£ervlces', 6ctoberTssl), PP. 6-7. annual rate of 218 million pounds ($6lO million). This would mean a doubling of the 1950 dollar deficit of 107 million pounds ($299 million). The sterling area's gold and dollar accounts showed a favorable trend in the first half of 1951 but deteriorated sharply in the second half. In the first half a gold and dollar surplus of $414 million was attained. As a result, the gold and dollar reserves of the sterling area rose to the a high of $5#867 million by the end of half-year. In half of the second 1951 there was a sharp reversal in the gold and dollar position of the sterling area, and a deficit of $1,578 was sustained. As a result, the deficit for the whole year amounted to $1,164 million, and at the o end of the year the reserves were down to $2,535 million. 8 1122 Sterling Area Facts and Figures, ID (British Information "Services/ January 1952)7 P* 9* It is too early to analyse in a precise manner the various factors contributing to the deterioration of Britain's balance-of-payments and reserve position in 1951* Some of them, however, are obvious and should be noted. The foremost cause of Britain's new difficulty appears to have been the steady increase in British import prices, especially in raw material prices, which began soon after the outbreak of the Korean war in June 1950. By June 1951 and Import prices had risen by 43 percent raw material the the prices by 76 percent over 1950 average. At same time, export prices rose by only 20 percent over the 1950 average. This failure of export prices to rise in propor­ tion with import prices caused a considerable worsening of the United Kingdom's terms of trade. By May 1951 the terms of trade were 20 percent worse than the 1950 average. The result was, of course, a substantial increase in import ex­ penditures, not offset by an equivalent increase in export earnings. Some of the increase in import expenditures was due to a higher volume of imports (partly for stockpiling and to replenish commercial stocks), but the greater part was due to the rise in import prices. After June 1951 there was a slight fall in British import prices, and raw material prices, while export prices continued to rise. By October 1951 import prices were 33 percent and raw material prices 46 percent higher than the 1950 average. In the same month export prices were 25 percent higher. As a result, the terms of trade improved considerably but were still 6 per- Q cent worse than the 1950 average. 9 Britain’s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, p. 2; and La'bor and Industry in Britain (British Information Services), Vol. IX, December 1951, P* 15^* Another important cause of the 1951 crisis was the was rearmament program which prompted by the critical world situation. The greater imports of raw materials needed by Britain to out its own rearmament effort, as well as carry the world-wide pressure on raw material supplies arising out of the world rearmament drive, sent the prices of lo Britain’s imports shooting upward. Furthermore, to meet 10 Britain’s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, p. 2. 160 the demands of rearmament, substantial resources had to be shifted from civilian and export production to military production. The main impact of this development appeals to have fallen on those industries which produce substantial­ 11 ly for export, such as coal and steel. Despite this strain 11 Labor and Industry in Britain, Vol. IX, December 1951, p. 15^ on Britain’s export Industries, the volume of exports in­ creased by about 3 percent during 1951* The volume of im­ -12 ports, however, increased by about 15 percent. 12 British Record, January 22, 1952, p. 4. Another factor which appears to have contributed to the 1951 crisis was the loss of Iranian oil. Although there no specific figures at this time to indicate are the magnitude of this loss, there is no doubt that the nationalization of the Iranian oil industry has cut deeply into the invisible earnings of the United Kingdom. Two other factors contributed to the deterioration of the sterling area’s position in 1951-First, there was considerable increase in the dollar imports of both the a 161 and the rest of the sterling area. In the United Kingdom first half of 1951 United Kingdom dollar imports rose to an annual rate of $1,680 million, as compared with $1,200 million in 1950. The dollar imports of the rest, of the sterling area rose to an annual rate of $1,090 million in the first half of 1951, as compared with $715 million in 1950. Secondly, the prices of sterling area raw materials had begun to fall in the first half of 1951* This price fall, coupled with decreased purchases by dollar countries, very probably led to a sharp fall In dollar earnings by countries In the second half of overseas sterling 1951 (no available specific figures are ).^ 13 Britain’s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, p. 4. Still another cause of Britain's trouble in 1951 was the loss of gold to the European Payments Union. Until April 1951 Britain had a substantial surplus (partly on her own and partly on other sterling countries' accounts) with the E. P. U. In May this surplus turned into a deficit which continued throughout the rest of the year. As a result, Britain had to repay $ll9 million in gold which she re­ ceived when she was in surplus, and, since October, to make 162 additional gold payments amounting to $9B million. The effect of these losses of to weaken Britain's was, course, 14 gold and dollar position. 14 British Record, October 31, 1951, P» 4, and Janu­ary 8, 1955/Ip There were, perhaps, other factors in Britain's balance-of-payments crisis of 1951* Those noted above the most important, or least the most obvious, ones. The relative importance of each is, at Lhis time, impossible to assess. The 1951 crisis is more disturbing than the 1949 crisis for two reasons. First, there was a substantial reduction in the United Kingdom's balance-of-payments surplus with the rest of the sterling area in the first half of 1951* This was due to the fact that for the first time the United other members of the Kingdom had a trade deficit with the IS It must be remembered that in the first area. sterling 15 British Record, October 31, 1951# p. 3« half of 1949, while the United Kingdom had a large balance- of..payments deficit with the dollar area, it maintained a substantial surplus with the rest of the sterling area. Partly because of that surplus, the United Kingdom was able to maintain a small overall balance-of-payments surplus in the first half of the other sterling countries was considerably smaller. Partly because of this reduced surplus, the United Kingdom sustained a substantial overall balance-of-payments deficit in the first half of 1951* Secondly, the new crisis is not, as in mainly a problem of trade between the it is not crisis charac­ sterling and dollar areas, i.e., a the terized chiefly by a large deficit in sterling area’s transactions with the dollar area. To be sure, the dollar deficit remains large, but the current crisis is primarily "a crisis." In addition to general balance of payments the United Kingdom,"other members of the Sterling Area are in overall deficit." As a matter of fact. ....the whole Sterling Area is in deficit all round the world... It follows that there is not at the time as sharp a distinction present as there was in recent years between so-called hard currencies and so-called soft ies. 16 Labor and Industry In Britain, Vol. IX, December 1951, P« 157. Quoted from the speech or Mr. H. A. Bucler, the new Chancellor of the Exchequer, to the House of Com­ mons on November 7* 1951> In which he outlined Britain's economic position and announced measures to deal with the critical situation. 164 There are Indications that the situation may be­ come worse. It has been estimated that on present trends, Britain would have a balance-of-payments deficit of between 500 and 600 million pounds in 1952, and "the gold and dol­ lar deficit of the Sterling Area would be still larger. 17 Labor and Industry in Britain, Vol. IX, December 1951, P-15^ Such deficits would set Britain back to the position she held In 194?, when her overall balance-of-payments deficit amounted to million pounds and the sterling area ! s gold and dollar deficit amounted to 1,024 million pounds ($4,151 million). Chapter VI BRITAIN'S DILEMMA The usefulness of devaluation a currency as means of correcting a fundamental balance-of-payments disequi­ librium has frequently been questioned. As a short-term measure it may have certain merits, but as a device to achieve it a permanent solution, may not necessarily be successful. Britain's new balance-of-payments crisis em­ phasizes this view in a convincing manner. The devalua­ tion of 1949 brought temporary relief to the British situa- It dealt with the immediate cause of the tion. 1949 crisis and enabled Britain to make a substantial improvement in international payments in 1950* But once the favorable ef­ fects of the devaluation had worn off, Britain's funda­ mental problem came to the fore once again, aggravated by the Korean war. Britain's current crisis cannot, however, be at­ tributed entirely to the failure of sterling devaluation as a long-term solution. As pointed out in Chapter V, there were other factors which contributed to the deterioration of Britain's position. They might have produced a crisis regardless of the effects of devaluation. But it must be most remembered that one of the important of these factors was a substantial deterioration of Britain's terms of trade 165 in 1951. The devaluation of sterling, as might have been expected, contributed heavily to this adversity in the terms of trade. Again, there were factors other than de­ valuation that had an adverse effect on Britain’s terms of trade, e.g., the rearmament drive which caused raw material prices to soar. But the terms of trade had been deteriorating since devaluation and would have continued to deteriorate regardless of the external pressure on raw material prices. Since devaluation has proven unsuccessful in deal- what ing with Britain’s long-term problem, alternatives re­ main? What new policies and measures are dictated by the ineffectiveness of devaluation and the of the cur- urgency rent crisis? The British Government has adopted certain short-term measures designed to deal with the present dif­ ficulty, as well as long-range policies which, it is hoped, will ultimately solve Britain’s basic problem. Immediate efforts will be concentrated on attain- increase It is ing a substantial in exports. felt that, the current exchange rate and current prices, given Britain’s external accounts will balance only if the volume of her exports is increased enough to earn the means of pay- she of the ing for the imports needs. The problem expanding volume of exports seems to be closely related to the problem of production. The Increase in the value of United Kingdom exports which was attained in 1950 and maintained in 1951* was chiefly the result of rather than higher export prices an increase in the volume of exports. The volume of United Kingdom exports has increased very little since devaluation In 1951 it was about 13 to 20 percent above the volume This small increase in large due to the fact was, measure, that British industrial production increased by an even smaller the percentage during same period. In 1951 indus­ trial production in the United Kingdom was only about 12 level.^ percent above the 1 Rough estimates from figures International in Financial Statistics, Vol. V, January 1952, pp. 112-115. Thus, if Britain is to seek the remedy for her balance-of-payments difficulty by stressing an increase in the volume of exports, she must increase her industrial production substantially. Special attention must be given to steel. Britain will need more steel to produce "more ships, cars, machinery, and engineering products" for 2 export. The British Government apparently feels that the 2 British Record (British Information Services), P. ~t>7~ January 87 key to the whole problem must be found in increased pro­ duction and is determined to do everything in its power to achieve that increase. "The only ultimate solution,” said Chancellor Butler in his speech to the Commons on November 7, 1951* Mmust be one of expansion. We are de­ termined to get output and the to up encourage country more...."^ produce 3 Quoted in Labor and Industry in Britain (British Information Services), Vol. , £>ecember 15517 P • 157» How is Britain to achieve this increase in her in­ dustrial production? An immediate increase in the number of industrial workers is unlikely. Since the the war, British economy has been operating at or near full employ­ ment, and labor reserves are negligible. Greater production must come by means other than a larger working force. The logical alternative is an increase in industrial efficiency. A large portion of British Industry is in dire need of new The introduction of plant and equipment. more modern equip­ ment and techniques would, very likely, increase the pro- worker. ductivity of the British industrial But the re- equipment of industry would require machinery and other capital goods that are urgently needed for export. Further- a substantial share of British production will go more, Into the rearmament program. What is more distressing is the fact that the steel shortage will make it extremely difficult to increase industrial production enough to pro­ vide for industrial re-equipment, rearmament, and a sub­stantially larger volume of exports in the immediate future An attack on the balance-of-payments problem from the side of imports faces even greater obstacles than the approach from the side of exports. Further import cuts are impossible if essential foodstuffs and raw materials are to be imported in sufficient quantities to maintain a tolerable standard of living and a level of production which satisfies rearmament and other consumption needs. The Government has already announced import cuts designed to save 500 million pounds ($1,400 million) a year. Since they consist largely of cuts in imports of food and con­ sumer goods, the burden will fall mainly on the British 4 consumer. 4 British Record, January J>l, 1952, p. 2. New cuts in raw material Imports would seriously the rearmament and export programs. Britain must endanger materials to keep industrial production at a high raw have Efforts will, therefore, have to be concentrated level. 170 on lowering raw material prices. In this respect, Britain will have to rely primarily on external forces over which she has no direct control. The pressure on world supplies of raw materials must be eased If prices to decline. are Whether this can be done depends on whether the world re­ armament drive can be slowed down, which In turn depends on political and military considerations arising out of future world events. As its contribution to relieving the pressure on raw materials, the British Government plans to slow down its own stockpiling program. The rate of this slow-down will, of course, be limited by the needs of industry to meet rearmament and export requirements. Lower raw mate­ rial prices would help considerably to reduce import expendi­ tures. with the new cuts In of food and Together imports to- consumer goods mentioned above, they would go a long way ward closing the trade gap. One very important aspect of the Import problem should be considered. This is the possibility of reducing Britain’s import expenditures by increased home production the efforts have been of foodstuffs. Since war, vigorous to increase food production in made, with notable success, Britain is still the world’s the United Kingdom. Although largest importer of foodstuffs (she imports about 60 percent of of what she eats), she is now producing about 40 percent her food (in terms of calories), "as compared with about 50 per cent before World War II.H The post-war increase in Britain's domestic food production has been the result of "carefully worked out policies supported, where necessary, by Government aid." In 1947 a policy was put Into effect, under the Agriculture Act of that year, designed to increase output to 50 percent above the 1938 level by 1952-53-Much of the success is, of course, due to increased mechanization 5 and increased use of fertilizers. Whether home production 5 Vol. December Labor and Industry In Britain, IX, 164-Ibb. 1951> pp. can be raised enough to cut down substantially on future food imports is a moot question. Certainly, the Government policy of encouraging greater production of foodstuffs in the United Kingdom should be continued. Greater mechaniza­ tion, use of the latest and most efficient methods of cultl vatlon and livestock breeding, and utilization of more un­ to used land could possibly increase food production enough allow a substantial reduction in Britain's food Imports and still assure a high level of consumption. The immediate problem in achieving this goal is, of course, whether the will be spared by the rearmament and export in- resources dustries for the production of more agricultural equipment 172 and industrial fertilizers. The future for Britain's invisible trade is un­ certain, and the prospects for substantial aid from this source in solving the balance-of-payments problem are dim. To be invisible earnings have been steadily increas­ ing since the war, and the improvement in Britain's posi­ tion in 1950 was largely due to a substantial increase in invisible earnings. However, it is doubtful whether further substantial increases can be made in shipping re- the two ceipts and in income from overseas investments, most important items in Britain's invisible trade. Greater commercial shipping space depends on increased ship construction, which in turn will be limited by the shortage of steel and the priority claims of the rearmament and ex­ port programs on available manpower. And the large losses of Investments sustained during the war have not been overseas replaced by new investment in a large enough proportion to a volume of income equal to or greater than the yield pre­war level in the near future. The unsettled international situation and Britain's diminishing empire have, of course, limited the opportunities for new Investment. A severely net invisible of reduction in Britain's income would, course, aggravate the balance-of-payments problem. But even if in- were maintained at its present level, it might be of come small help in solving the problem. To offset a possible increase in the visible trade deficit, a substantial in­ crease in net invisible earnings would be necessary. Such an Increase is unlikely in the near future. Even If Britain were able to implement all the measures and make all the adjustments necessary to expand reduce and her exports, her Imports, increase her net in­ visible even if all the external factors earnings, affect­ ing her balance of payments were favorable, she would still fail to solve her problem unless steps were taken to stabi­ lize her internal economy and increase internal production. However drastic, any action designed to deal with the ex­ ternal aspects of the problem, and this includes devalua­ tion, will be unsuccessful unless it is supported by ade­ internal measures. quate more resources of men and materials diverted As are to meet the needs of the rearmament and export programs, less will be available for production of consumer goods to at home. There be satisfy civilian needs will, however, no corresponding reduction of purchasing power. Unless are taken to hold back the increased demand on this steps limited supply of consumer goods, inflation will be un­ avoidable. The effect of internal inflationary pressures Britain's external trade should be obvious. As sterling on 174 prices rise at home, British goods will seem less attractive and to foreign buyers the proposed export Increases will be much more difficult to attain. To export more, Britain must Devaluation or hold down sterling prices. any other measure to designed improve Britain’s competitive posi­ tion on the world market will futile If the prove prices of British goods continue to rise. Unless internal demand can be checked, such a price rise will be forthcoming. But Inflation will also have an adverse effect on Imports, for higher sterling prices at home would encourage more Imports of cheaper foreign goods to satisfy consumer de­ mand . Strict Inflationary controls by the Government must Intensified. be continued and. If necessary. Taxation, however painful, will undoubtedly continue to be the Government’s chief anti-inflatlonary weapon. The burden of heavy taxes has been a severe strain on the British people since the war, but if purchasing power Is to be substantially curtailed, taxes will have to be kept high. not Government bonds, redeemable for, say, 20 years, would also be an effective check on consumer demand. Wage even further will be virtual- reductions to restrict demand ly Impossible, because no British Government, whether to commit Laborlte or Conservative, would wish political cuts for British workers. The suicide by supporting wage 175 Government may even find 1g Impossible to prevent wage In­ creases. A further rise in the cost of living will bring demands for higher wages from British trade unions. In the export Industries holding wages down Is a prime neces­ sity If production costs, and hence export prices, are to be kept down. This, however, would limit the voluntary migration of labor to the export Industries, and would necessitate to channel the government controls necessary manpower Into these Industries. Price controls also face serious difficulties. If the general price level is kept high in o~der to restrict purchasing power, the Inflation­ ary pressure on export prices may prevent the desired ex­ pansion In exports* If general prices are reduced in order to keep export prices down, purchasing power will be en­ hanced. The logical solution to this problem may be to allow prices of consume'1 goods to remain high, while Im­ posing strict controls on the prices of exports and materials used in the production of exports. This, however, would reduce the profit Incentive In the export and related Industries, and would necessitate further controls to channel capital Into these essential Industries. Certain large public expenditures undertaken by the Labor Government and which, for the most part, must now be continued by the Conservatives, have a definite on inflationary effect the economy. Yet, substantial re­ ductions in government expenditures are highly improbable in the near future. Britain’s international committments, especially her role in the North Atlantic alliance, re­ quire the maintenance of large armed forces and heavy mili­ tary expenditures. Unless there is a sudden improvement in the international situation, than an increase, rather a reduction, may be forthcoming in government military spend- The social ing. services, likewise, face little or no reduction. Like the problem of wage reductions, this is a touchy political issue, and the Conservative Government will want to avoid tampering with it. As a matter of fact, the Government has announced that the structure of the social services is to remain Intact; however, new charges, expected to yield some 40 million pounds, will be intro­ duced for some parts of the National Health Service.^ r o British Record, January 31, 1952, pp. 3-4. Other* measures designed to maintain internal financial stability were announced by Chancellor of the Butler in his November 1951 speech to the Com- Exchequer mons. These include proposed cuts in building and capital investment designed to save materials, especially steel, and labor which are more urgently needed to carry out the 177 rearmament and export new restraints on programs; personal incomes and spending through "a very cautious policy of . dividend distribution" and an excess profits tax to be introduced on January 1, 1952; and a rise in the rate of Interest as well as other credit controls designed to restrict bank credit to essential purposes.^ 7 Labor and Industry in Britain, Vol. IX, December 1951, pp.~TSB-1.59. To a very large extent, many of Britain's troubles are due to external forces over which she alone has no control. Her rearmament program and her large military expenditures overseas stem, of course, from the current world tension. A substantial lessening of this tension would permit a substantial reduction In Britain's military production and expenditure. Whether such an Improvement in the world situation is possible In the near future Is primarily a political question, and one which Britain alone Influence. Certainly, she should do all in her power cannot a but this will have to be done to bring about settlement, in the context of international negotiations. primarily The unsettled international conditions that have prevailed in the post-war period are, of course, also responsible for the instability that afflicts the world economy. In such unstable conditions, world trade in general and British foreign trade in particular cannot thrive. It may be said that, in the final analysis, the solution to Britain’s problem depends upon the restoration of world economic stability and the creation of a more favorable international trade setting. Whether this can be done in the immediate future also which depends upon forces Britain alone cannot control. In this respect, the United States can play a very important role. As a matter of fact, the success of Britain’s new economic policies will depend largely upon the stability of the American economy. This is not an idle statement. It must be remembered that the small de­ pression that took place in the United States in the lat­ ter half of and the first half of caused a re­ duction in United States imports of British goods. This reduction contributed heavily to the gold and dollar losses the British crisis of and led to the that precipitated devaluation of sterling. If Britain is to find a market for her exports in the United States, the American economy must be maintained at a high level of employment and in­ come. Furthermore, tariff restrictions on British goods entering the United States will have to be substantially 179 reduced and In some cases (provided no undue hardship is Imposed on the Industries affected) abolished. Many Americans complain about United States aid to Britain. They maintain that Britain’s troubles are not our fault and that we should not be asked for them. to pay Yet, they fail to realize that unless we are willing to buy more British goods, Britain will face a continuing deficit in her balance of payments which will make her increasingly dependent on foreign aid to finance her pur­ chases of food and raw materials. The only logical source of such aid is, of course, the United States. For the British people, the road ahead looks ex­ tremely difficult. The implementation of the policies outlined in the foregoing pages does not guarantee a solution of Britain’s balance-of-payments problem. It may be noued that their practical application would, in raise new and more difficult problems which many cases, would require new and more stringent measures. The steel and the priority claims of rearmament and exports shortage seem to be the chief stumbling blocks upon which most of the proposals for dealing with the British problem disinte- This is not to that these grate into new problems. say policies would be totally ineffective and that their adoption is a futile gesture. Even if they do not achieve a 180 permanent solution, they are necessary to meet the cur­ rent and will crisis; if applied with sufficient vigor, they put Britain well on the road toward external solvency. For the individual Britisher, the immediate future holds greater sacrifices than he has heretofore experienced. The austerity he has learned to bear so patiently will be in­ tensified, and the improved standard of living which he has so long expected will have to be postponed indefinitely. He will be taxed more. He will find less consumer goods available and will have to pay higher prices for those he for the most buys. His food consumption will, part, re­ main at present levels, but he will have to face actual cuts in some items. Emphasis on increased British production is well Greater industrial production and domestic placed. pro­ duction of foodstuffs has a favorable effect on the balance of payments and will, in the long run. Improve the standard of living. On the other hand, the rearmament has an adverse effect on the balance of payments, program directly, by limiting the resources that can be allocated the for export production, and indirectly, by intensifying inflationary pressures which worsen the terms of trade. has an adverse effect on the standard of Rearmament also living by limiting the supply of consumer goods. Britain, thus, finds Itself on the horns of a dilemma. In this situation, sterling devaluation, far from being a cure (a few Individuals have suggested a further devaluation of the pound), will only make the terms of trade worse and the aggravate malady. BIBLIOGRAPHY Books Abrams, M. (ed.), Britain and Her Export Trade, London: Pilot 19467 Britain and World Trade, London; PEP, 1947. Ellsworth, P. T. The International Economy, New York: The MacMlllan^Corapany, 19507 PP7"~S4T-545; 573-577; 739-753* of League Nations, Commercial Policy in tne Interwar Period; InternetionaT Proposals and Natfonal Policies, T94P7 (j-eneva, , Industrialization and Foreign Trade, 1945* Liepmann, H. Tariff Levels and the Economic Unity of Europe, translated by H 7 ~§iTenning, London; George Allen & Unwin Ltd., 1938. The Scope Yearbook of Industry, Trade and Finance, London; Scope 60ofcs Ltcf7i lssl- Articles Balogh, T. "Britain's Foreign Trade Problem; A Comment", Economic Journal, Vol. LVIII, March 1948, pp. 74-85. V. M. "British Reconversion and Trade", Foreign Dacey, Affairs, Vol. 23, January 1945, PP* 247-^557 Ellis, H. S. “The Dollar Shortage in Theory and Fact", The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science ;"VoT 7 'T47~August' Harris, S. E. "Devaluation of the Pound Sterling", Harvard Business Review, Vol. XXVII, November 19?9, Dp 7 781­7W. F. "British Postwar Balance of Inter- Heatherington, D. national Payments", Foreign Commerce Weekly, voi. xx, August 25, 1545 PP• "5-s’> 5-48. , 182 183 Henderson, Sir Hubert, "The Moral of the British Crisis”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. XXXI, November '194"9/ PP. 'ss6-266. Leffingwell, R. C. "Devaluation and European Recovery”, Foreign Affairs, Vol. 28, January 1950, pp. 203-214. MacDougall, G. D. A. "Britain’s Foreign Trade Problem”, Economic Journal, Vol. LVII, March 1947, pp. 69-113. Polak, J. J. "Contribution of the September 1949 Devalua­ tions to the Solution of Europe’s Dollar Problem", Staff Papers (international Monetary Fund), Vol. 11, September 1951, pp. 1-32. Polk, J. and Patterson, G. "The British Loan”, Foreign Affairs, Vol. 24, April 1946, pp. 429-440. "Readjustment of Foreign Currency Values”, Federal Reserve Vol. Bulletin, 35, October 1949, ppTTIt9-IfBl. on Robbins, L. "inquest the Crisis", Lloyds Bank Review, New Series, October 1947, pp. 1-^7* Williams, J. H. "The British Crisis: A Problem in Economic Statesmanship”, Foreign Affairs, Vol. 28, October 1949, PP-1-17­ United Kingdom Public Documents A-Command Papers Cmd. 6707, Statistical Material Presented During the Washington Negotiations, London: His Majesty 1 s Stationery office, December 1945* Cmd. 6708, Financial Agreement Between the Governments of the United Stages and the Unlied Xlngddm, London: His Majesty's Stationery (3ffice, December 1945* and on the Settle Cmd. 6904, Financial Agreement Agreement ment ol1 Vaf ‘Claims' "Between the CjOveVnmenLs of the~ United Kingdom and Canada, London: His Majesty rs Stationery Office, September 1946. for His Cmd. 7647, Economic Survey 1949, London: Majesty' March T949. Stationery Office, 184 Cmd. 7793, United Kingdom Balance of Payments to London; Hfs Ma jVs ty fs Stationery office, October 1949. Cmd. 7928, United Kingdom Balance of Payments to No. 2, London: His Majesty's Stationery Office, April 1950. Cmd. Balance of 8065, Unibed Kingdom Payments to 195Q, London; His Ma jesty i Stationery Office, October s 1950. B. Other Accounts Relating to Trade and Navigation of the United Kingdom, London; Hfs Majesty rs Stationery Office. Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 85, London; His Majesty *sStatloneryoffice, I§4B. Annual Abstract of Statistics, No. 87, London; r His MaJe3ty s~"Stationery Office, 1951* Britain 1 s Balance of Payments Position, ID 1093, British Informatlon Services, October 1951* Sterling Area Facts and Figures, ID 1122, British Informa­ tfon Service's, January 1952. Periodicals The Board of Trade Journal (London). British Record (British Information Services). Canadian Statistical Review (Ottawa). The Economist (London). International Financial Statistics (International Monetary Fund) Labor* and Industry in Britain (British Information Services). The Statist (London). Survey of Current Business Vital Speeches of the Da The vita has been removed from the digitized version of this document.