LYNDON B. JOHNSON SCHOOL OF PUBLIC AFFAIRS POLICY RESEARCH PROJECT REPORT • • Number JO Cf'1 g A STUDY OF THE FEASIBILITY OF NO-FAULT AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE FOR TEXAS 0. 0 Zap A Report by The State Insurance Policy Research Project Lyndon B. Johnson School ofPublic Affairs The UniFersity of Texas at Austin 1975 FOREWORD The Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs has established inter­disciplinary research on policy problems as the core of its educational program. A major part of this program is the policy research project, in the course of which three faculty members, each from a different profession or discipline, and about fifteen graduate students with diverse backgrounds research a policy issue of concern to an agency of government. This "client orientation" brings the students face to face with administrators, legislators, and other officials active in the policy process., and demonstrates that research in a policy environment demands special talents. It also illuminates the difficulties of using research findings to bring about change where political realities must be taken into account. This report on the feasibility of no-fault automobile insurance for Texas was produced by the State Insurance Policy Research Project at the LBJ School during the 1973-74 academic year. It was one of two studies undertaken at the request of the Texas State Board of Insurance and its Chairman, Joe Christie. The second study was on the feasibility of health maintenance organizations for Texas. The intention of the LBJ School is both to develop men and women with the capacity to perform 1effectively in public service and to produce research that will enlighten and inform those already engaged in the policy process. The project which resulted in these reports has helped to accomplish the former; it is our hope and expectation that the reports themselves will contribute to the latter. William B. Cannon Dean iii TABLE OF CONTENTS FOREWORD iii PREFACE v POLICY RESEARCH PROJECT PAR TIC IPANTS vii CHAPTER I: THE TORT AUTOMOBILE REPARATIONS SYSTEM: PROBLEM OR PROMISE The Development of Tort Law The Current System and Its Problems 4 Criteria for Reform: The Characteristics of a Good Automobile Insurance System 5 CHAPTER II : THE THEORY OF A NO-FAULT AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE SYSTEM 9 The History of No-Fault Automobile Insurance 9 Types of No-Fault Laws 11 Limiting the Right to Sue 17 CHAPTER III: SPECIAL ISSUES AND PROBLEMS 21 The Constitutionality of No-Fault Automobile Insurance 21 The Potential Shift in Rates Among Insureds Under No-Fault Insurance: The Subrogation Issue 24 Coordination of Benefits: The Primacy Issue 26 Compulsory Automobile Insurance 32 CHAPTER IV: EXPERIENCES OF OTHER STATES WITH NO-FAULT INSURANCE 42 CHAPTER V: PROSPECTS FOR TEXAS 46 Characteristics of the Texas System 46 Recent Changes in t)J.e Texas System: Implications 48 Probable Effects of No-Fault Automobile Insurance for Texas 51 CHAPTER VI: ALTERNATIVES AND CONCLUSIONS 61 Proposed Modified No-Fault Plan 62 Proposed Modified Tort Liability Plan 62 BIBLIOGRAPHY 67 APPENDIX A: A COMPULSION/COMPLIANCE IN AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE: SURVEY QUESTIONNAIRE 71 APPENDIX B: ACCIDENT QUESTIONNAIRE 74 v PREFACE Historically , damages and injuries resulting from auto­mobile accidents in the United States have been remedied through a system of tort law which makes a determination of who is at fault for causing the injuries and damages in a particular case and assesses against him the responsibility for paying the losses. Accompanying this legal system is an insurance system under which persons deemed liable for injuries to persons and property could look to insurers to pay the judgment rather than their other personal financial resources. As a result of problems and criticisms associated with these systems, among them the fact that many accident victims receive no reparation for their losses , there has developed in recent years a number of so-called no-fault automobile insurance plans which make substantial changes in the manner of compensating automobile accident losses. The essential characteristic of these plans is that they pay basic benefits for certain losses directly to the insured regardless of fault while limiting, at least partially, the person's traditional right to sue for recompense of those losses. The no-fault plans in existence at the present time have been adopted by states in their role as insurance regulators, but within the past few years, there has also been proposed legislation for a national system of no-fault insurance under consideration in the Congress of the United States. / In light of these developments and the growing interest in possible no-fault legislation in Texas, the State Board of Insurance through its Chairman, Joe Christie, requested the Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs to conduct a study of the feasibility of no-fault automobile insurance for Texas. This study was one of two undertaken during the 1973-74 school year by one of the School's policy research project seminars, a regular organizational component of the School's academic program structured with three or four faculty members and fifteen graduate students. In the instant case, with two major projects to accomplish, the graduate students were organized into two task groups, with six members assigned to the no-fault insurance study and nine members to the study of health maintenance organizations. The names of students and faculty associated with this study of no-fault insurance are indicated on the following page with the exception of Jared E. Hazleton, associate professor of public affairs. Professor Hazleton initially coordinated the project, but departed on a leave of absence at the end of the fall semester and is not, therefore, associated with or responsible for the findings and recom­mendations of this report. With a broad mandate to study any and all aspects of no-fault automobile insurance, including an assessment of the relatively limited experience of other states and to formulate appropriate alternatives and recommendations with respect to possible changes in the Texas system, it was inevitable that there would be a high level of interest on the part of the many individuals and groups who have professional, economic, social, and individual interests in the matters under study. Accordingly, every effort was made to make contact with these persons and groups and to elicit their experiences, individual points of view, and recommendations. The results of this effort were most beneficial and rewarding to the project and its ultimate product as presented here, and we wish to express our gratitude for the valuable contributions made by all who assisted us. These persons are too numerous to mention here, but they are listed at the end of the study. All of the faculty and students associated with this project express their deepest appreciation to the State Board of Insurance, and particularly Chairman Christie , for the unique and challenging opportunity to engage in this project, for able and prompt technical support on numerous occasions, and for providing a portion of the financial resources required to complete the study. Lastly and importantly, we are indebted to the Ford Foundation for funding a portion of the costs involved in this research effort. Lynn F. Anderson Project Coordinator vii POLICY RESEARCH PROJECT PARTICIPANfS Mary Lucia Urban Barras, B.A. (Mathematics), Hood College; M.L.S. (Library Sciences), The University of Texas at Austin. Peter Alan Bernstein, B.A. (Political Science), Wesleyan University. Thomas Dana Denton, B.A. (Journalism), Baylor University; M.S.J. (Journalism), Northwestern University. James H. Mitchell, B.A. (Mathematics), Huston-Tillotson College. Richard Lynn Tate, B.A. (Government), Pan American University. Mike Moeller, B.S. (Speech), Southwest Texas State University. Jerry D. Todd, Associate Professor ofInsurance, Graduate School ofBusiness, The University of Texas at Austin. Sarah Haynie, Attorney, Texas Legislative Council, State of Texas, Austin, Texas. Monti Callero, Colonel, USAF, United States Air Force Associate, Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs, The University of Texas at Austin. Lynn F. Anderson, Associate Professor ofPublic Affairs and ofFinance and Director ofConferences and Training, Lyndon B. Johnson School ofPublic Affairs, The University ofTexas at Austin, Project Coordinator. ix CHAPTER I THE TORT AUTOMOBILE REPARATIONS SYSTEM: PROBLEM OR PROMISE THE DEVELOPMENT OF TORT LAW The chief function of government in any society is the maintenance of order. Rules are enacted providing that individuals should not impinge on the essential rights of others and discouraging willful disturbers of order from becoming disturbers again. Laws are enacted calling for the compensation of victims of disturbing activities so that these individuals may quickly become healthy members of society and so they do not feel that they must take revenge on the person who has done them a wrong. Order must be ' maintained. Governments, if they are to stay in' power, must provide sanctions against the disorderly, and must also take measures for insuring that the victims of disorder receive just and fair compensation for the wrongs that have been perpetrated against them. For the purpose of dealing with the disorder in society caused by automobile accidents, the United States has developed the "fault insurance system." This sytem is composed of two parts: (1) fault law, which determines who has caused the disorder; and (2) insurance, which is the means of correcting the wrong that has occurred. It is a system that theoretically deals punitively with the dis­orderly and also compensates victims so that they will not be encouraged to be disorderly themselves . Later portions of this report will deal with the ultimate feasibility of the total system. This section deals with the origin and development of tort law as it applies to automobiles and with some of the current problems facing this area of the law. It is noted that the law had to deal with the disorder caused by traffic accidents long before insurance became widely used to pay the bill. The Concepts of Tort Liability During the development of tort law there have been two concepts of liability : (1) the idea that men go about their daily activities at the risk of injuring others and are strictly liable for any injuries that may arise from their actions; and (2) the idea that a man is liable only for actions that were his fault. These concepts are as old as the history of tort law itself, and at one time or another each has been the guiding principle in the area of accidental physical damage. 1 * While the idea of fault has been around as long as the idea of tort law itself, the idea of negligence is a relatively new concept. In fact, the concept of negligence was a development of the nineteenth century. It arose from the . need for not placing an overly burdensome blame upon dangerous but useful activity. The industrial revolution needed an interpretation of the law that would protect it from having to spend its precious capital on the increasing number of injured workers. Proof that one's activities caused another's injuries was no longer sufficient as a grounds for the recovery of damages. Negligence had to be proved if any damage was to be compensated. It was this part of tort law that was applied to the first horse-and­buggy accidents, then railroad accidents, and finally to automobile accidents. Transportation was a dangerous but useful activity; and it needed protection to grow. Willful negligence was extremely hard to prove, and judges and juries who recognized the importance of industry to their communities were very unwilling to grant large damages even when negligence was proven. All industry anci not just transportation was in part subsidized by its innocent and unwilling victims. The cost of compensating the victim was definitely outweighed by the benefit derived by society from industry.2 This concept of negligence, which supplanted the con­cept of strict liability based on pure fault, was at its height at the turn of the century. Since that time the law has begun to swing the other way, beginning with the enact­ment of the first constitutional workmen's compensation law in 1911 in Wisconsin. The concept of strict liability­whereby one individual is held accountable for injuries to another regardless of fault-has become more and more dominant.3 In light of the ebb and flow of these varying concepts of tort liability it is interesting to examine just how and why they have grown in importance at one time or another. As *Footnotes at end of chapter, page 7. an important corollary it is also interesting to note the development of the negligence principle out of fault law, and the causes of its rise and apparent fall in importance in the field of automobile accidents. The Growth ofNegligence Law England, the birth place of our system of law, instituted the rudimentary steps in the development of common law with the introduction of the writ of trespass in the early thirteenth century. This was the first real attempt at maintaining order by something more advanced than the traditional approach of "an eye for an eye, and a tooth for a tooth." The remedies for wrongs during this period could only be gained by the issuance of a writ to bring a defendant into court, and only the king could issue such a writ since he determined what was to be considered by his court.4 Writs of trespass were issued for obvious breaches of the peace such as assaults, beatings, and destruction of property as well as unintentional actions which caused destruction of another's property. Trespass was totally criminal in nature, and if an action did not fall into one of the defined categories, then no remedy could be sought.5 The purpose of the original remedies in trespass cases was the punishment of the wrongdoer. Eventually, how­ ever, the courts realized that the peace could only be maintained if the victim of a crime received some compen­ sation for the wrong that had been done to him, and this aspect was incorporated into the deliberations of the judges and juries. The primary problem with the writ of trespass was that new cases began to appear that were not covered by writs, but needed to be covered. In order to deal with this situation: ...the King's Council (adopted) the Statute of Westminster II (in 1285) providing in substance that whenever in one case a writ was found and in like cases falling under like law no such writ was discoverable, Chancery was authorized, subject to certain precautions, to issue a new writ appropriate to the particular needs of the case before the court. Hence there came into being a companion form of action known as the action of trespass on the case. This form was available whenever the complaint showed a complete absence of force or an injury which 'was only indirectly afflicted. The new action had become familiar by the first half of the fourteenth 6century. An entirely new mode for recemng damages had been established, and our whole theory of tort liability was to spring from this new form of action. On face value it does not seem that anything new had happened with the adoption of the Statute of Westminster II. However, as Prosser points out in his casebook on torts: The distinction was not one between intentional and unintentional conduct. The emphasis was upon the causal sequence, rather than the character of the defendant's wrong. Trespass would lie for all forcible, direct injuries, even though they were not intended, while the action on case might be maintained for those which were intended but not forcible, . or not direct. There were, however, two significant points of difference between the two actions. Trespass, because of its quasi-criminal character, required no proof of any actual damage, since invasion of the plaintiff's rights by the criminal conduct was regarded as a tort itself; while in action on the case, which developed purely as a civil remedy, there could ordinarily be no liability unless actual damage was proved. Also, in its earlier stages trespass was identified with the view that liability might be imposed without regard to the defendant's fault while case from the beginning required proof of either wr~ngful intent or negligence.7 Fault had been established as an important part of the common law, and with the coming industrial revolution it was to become the most important part. The fact that fault had been established as a means of determining liability in cases where actions were uninten­tional did not mean that the idea of strict liability was immediately abandoned. The defendant in action on case still had his actions linked to the injury that was suffered by the plaintiff. The establishment of this causal link, which was still fairly easy, meant that the defendant would have to pay for the damage he had caused. The only way in which the defendant could get out of this payment was by showing that he was absolutely without fault. The burden of proof rested on the defendant, and it was to remain there until the early 1800s. In the early 1800s, due primarily to the great increase in horse-and-buggy traffic collisions, this simple basis of liability for unintended hurts was quickly and radically changed. . . . The defendant was no longer required to show that the injury was unavoidable or utterly without his fault . . . .His duty was so modified that he was required merely to exercise reasonable care in the operation of his horse or vehicle. Reasonable care depended on whether as an ordinary prudent man he should have foreseen some harm to the injured person or someone so situated.8 Freedom of the road-the cause and effect of the industrial revolution which could only thrive on mobility­in a few short years had caused the courts to replace strict liability with negligence. Society wanted its own fortunes increased and this meant that risks associated with traveling had to be greatly reduced. With the adoption of the concept of negligence in traffic accidents a traveler would only risk his fortune if a plaintiff could prove that he had not acted as a reasonable man would have acted. The burden of proof had been placed on the victim. Society, through its courts, had determined that the new order being brought about by the industrial revolution was an order that needed protection under the law.9 2 It must be pointed out that much of our law is not based on eternal natural rights, but on principles of morality and public policy which change over time. This is especially significant in the case of torts. Rulings in this area tend to reflect and protect the pervasive moral and political values during a given period of time. During the nineteenth century the prevailing public policy was that of making what was good for industry good for society. Negligence law both reflects this attitude and protects individuals in order that the attitude might become a reality. Just how far this protection extended can be seen in its application to traffic accidents. . . .If neither party had failed to exercise reasonable care, the collision was an accident and no liability ensued ..... If the danger was obvious, the victim assumed the risk. If he failed to exercise reasonable care for his own safety, even if the dangers were obvious, he too was negligent and could recover nothing for his injury. (This is the concept of contributory negligence.) If the injury was fatal, there could be no recovery for the injuries suffered before death or for death itself. And what is more, the victim was given the burden of proving his case at every step-the burden of showing that the defendant had harmed the victim ; that the law imposed a duty on the defendant to exercise care with respect to the victim; that he had failed to exercise reasonable care in his behalf; that the harm inflicted was a proximate consequence of defendant's conduct and not remote; ·that the victim had himself exercised reasonable care for his own safety; and what losses the victim suffered. 10 Under these conditions, a plaintiff who was contributorily negligent could receive damages from a defendant only if he could prove that the defendant had enough time to see that an accident would be occurring, and subsequently did not take action to avoid it. Only if this could be proved could a victim's contributory negligence during the accident not defeat his suit. The Decline ofNegligence Law The staggering toll in property and human life that resulted from uncontrolled adventures of industry into more and more hazardous areas was a leading factor in bringing about the reform movement in this country at the turn of the century. Society decided that it could no longer pay the price in human capital which industry needed as input into its production schedules. The benefits of industry were outweighed by the costs to the families of injured individuals and to society as a whole. Child labor laws, 40-hour work weeks, and workmen's compensation were all adopted to reduce the number of victims of industrial mishaps. (Workmen's compensation encouraged factory owners to adopt safer procedures so that they would not have to be faced with paying large sums to accident victims.) Negligence law was modified to provide greater assurance to injured workers that they would be reimbursed for medical expenses and wage losses. Problem or Promise The concept of strict liability was reinstated in the area of job-related injuries. Workmen's compensation was the first, and probably most sensational return to the idea of strict liability. Employers were seen by the courts as being strictly liable for accidents that took place on their premises. Since the end of World War II there have been mounting efforts to replace negligence with strict liability in other areas-Le., product liability. In the area of automobile insurance, however, many are stressing just the opposite position. While negligence law is declared to be inadequate, it is suggested that the victim bear his own loss rather than hold anyone strictly liable . There is a different relationship between causer and victim in the driving situation than in the work situation. It is one thing to hold strictly liable the owner of a factory, or even the manufacturer of a product, but in most automo­bile accidents it would be almost impossible to prove that General Motors, for example, was the principal cause of every collision-nor could the price of automobiles embody the cost of accidents occurring in them over the years. In admitting that there is a significant difference between automobile accidents and those other accidents resulting from modern technology, this is not to say that the courts have not recognized the fact that the concept of negligence needed to be changed to meet the needs of the growing number of victims. Negligence may have been retained in this area, but that does not mean it has not undergone some changes. Action by the Courts A major change in the law of negligence as it applies to automobile accidents has been the introduction of the principle of res ipsa loquitur. This is a Latin phrase meaning that the action speaks for itself. The increasing use of this principle has made it easier for plaintiffs to win suits by in effect switching the burden of proof to the defendant. If the very nature of the accident indicates that the defendant was at fault, then the court will put the burden of proof on the defendant to show that he was not negligent. The courts have also decided that violation of some provisions of the motor vehicle code, traffic provisions, or highway safety acts should be construed as being "negli­gence per se." In other words, a violation of certain laws automatically makes the violator negligent and thus respon­sible for his tort. This imposition of strict liability has been of great help to many potential plaintiffs. Other areas in which the courts and legislatures have acted on behalf of the interests of plaintiffs are : (1) the abrogation of traditional common law immunities for charities and governments; (2) the increased use of the vicarious liability concept-Le., looking to employers and others responsible for the use or even the manufacture of 3 the automobile for compensation; (3) the defense of assumption of risk has been restricted or eliminated as an independent defense; and (4) 'the defense of contributory negligence has been qualified by the doctrine of last clear chance or even converted into comparative negligence. lbis is the current state of the tort liability law as it applies to automobile accidents. The negligence law of the nineteenth century, while not having been substantially changed in substance, has been procedurally altered in an attempt to reflect the value of an age in which automobile drivers have shown a propensity for colliding and thereby causing injury to their occupants. THE CURRENT SYSTEM AND ITS PROBLEMS As was noted earlier, the tort liability section of the law is only half of the "fault insurance system," and even this part has drawn criticism. However, when coupled with insurance, even the staunchest supporters of the current system of accident reparations see a need for modification. One of the main problems with the fault insurance system appears to be the inherent conflict between the concept of liability based on fault and liability insurance: Fault law, in theory shifts accident costs to wrongdoers. Liability insurance in theory, protects wrongdoers both by defense and by indemnity ....Liability insurance has stripped fault law of its purpose, but society is left to pay for and endure all the complexities of fault law decision-making. The emergence of the third expectation about the fault insurance. system-that it compensates victims-simply heightens the 11 tension among the purposes of the fault insurance system. The result is a system that has been openly criticized on many grounds. One of the chief criticisms is that the system provides no reparation at all for many accident victims. There are several reasons for this. First, to be reimbursed for damages, the plaintiff must prove that the defendant was negligent. A plaintiff who cannot prove negligence, for whatever reason, will not recover anything. The ability to prove negligence is dependent on so many unpredictable variables, such as geographic location, time lapsed since the accident, exis­ tence and qualifications of witnesses, quality of attorneys, and many more, that little consistency exists even among similar cases. Second, even if the plaintiff can prove negligence on the part of the defendant he will not recover anything if he was contributorily negligent in those states where comparative negligence has · not been instituted. (Texas adopted comparative negligence effective in August, 1973 .) He may also be restricted from recovery by guest statutes. (Texas has a modified guest statute in force, which restricts recovery only as to suits between certain family members.) Third, the plaintiff may be injured by someone who is financially irresponsible and who, therefore, cannot pay for the damages caused ~ven though he is legally liable to pay for such damages. Delay in the payment to accident victims is another problem of the current system. The 1970 U.S. Department of Transportation studies revealed that within 30 days after the occurrence of automobile accidents, on the average only 21 percent of paid claims had been settled. These settlements represented only 3.5 percent of the total payments made on all paid claims.12 The studies further showed that 90-day delays are not unusual and frequently years pass before some claims are paid.13 Perhaps most significantly, the tort system is said to be the cause of inequitable overpayments and underpayments to accident victims. One study provides the example of a person with an actual loss of $250 who files a claim for $1,000 against the other driver and his insurer. lbis prospective plaintiff may well receive $1,000 in an out-of­court settlement because the cost of a $250 claim plus the cost of defending the claim in court would exceed $1,000.14 Thus, the expense of litigation imposed by the tort system can cause an insurance company to agree out-of-court to pay the claimant an amount much higher than he or she deserves. On the other hand, when higher claims do, in fact, go to court, there is a tendency for these claims to be underpaid. Still another DOT study provided some documentation for this unusual dichotomy. The DOT statistics revealed that seriously injured victims with medical expenses of $5 ,000 or more recovered only 55 percent of their expenses from tort insurance while victims with medical expenses of less than $5 ,000 recovered an 15 average of 90 percent of expenses.There is, of course, much that can be questioned about these statistics (i.e., the validity of claimed medical expenditures). Likewise, there is some question as to the extensiveness of this under­payment/overpayment phenomenon throughout .the 50 states. However, logic and documentation indicate that both can and do occur as a result of the uncertainties involved in court trials of automobile injury cases (see Chapter Five). The finding of guilt involved in tort laws mandates that human injury, suffering, and degrees of guilt be translated into dollar and .cents figures. State Farm Automobile Insurance Company officials assert that these requirements have ''undoubtedly added costs to the reparation system."16 The 1970 Department of Transportation study provides some quantification of this excessive cost. According to the OOT's figures, in automobile accident litigation the defendant's attorneys receive an average of $819 per case regardless of the verdict.17 These costs are passed back through the automobile insurance system to the consumer. Critics charge that the current system has a number of other flaws: (1) There is a tremendous inducement for dishonesty due, in no small measure, to the large amounts of money that are involved in some cases. (2) The system does not provide adequate money for rehabilitation. (3) It 4 Problem or Promise fails in large degrees to deter negligent driving. (4) In reality, the system has very little to do with reparations because 97 percent of all claims are settled out-of-court. Thus, the concepts of negligence and fault are being handl~d in large. measure by insurance companies, or at least m proceedmgs that have very little to do with the concepts of what is fair and right for society .1 8 A 1971 DOT publication said of the relationship ~tween inflation in the rest of the economy and the mflated costs of automobile insurance: Perhaps the most pervasive influence upon automobile insurance as a public issue in recent years has been inflation. Indeed, between 1960 and 1970, the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for automobile insurance rose 63 percent, slightly more than twice as much as the CPI for . all items....This rise...was caused in large part by cost increases in the products and services which insurance pays for •...19 This drastic inflation of automobile insurance premiums is caused not only by increased labor costs and hospitaliza­tion and medical expenses, but, to a great degree by the rapidly increasing cost of automobile parts. State Farm has indicated that the greatest potential for cutting automobile insurance costs lies in the area of vehicle damage rather than bodily injury.20 That company reports that, according to its studies, the cost of crash replacement parts (bumpers, fenders, etc.) rose 104.7 percent from rnid-1963 to rnid­1974 while Bureau of Labor Statistics studies show that the cost of new cars increased only 10 percent during that same period.21 Statistics from the Insurance Information Insti­tute bear this out. According to these figures, the costs of repairing frequently damaged parts on a standard size 4-door Chevrolet sedan, 1967 model, were $231.65 for parts, $90.60 for labor or a total of $322.25. On a comparable 1973 model, the costs were $494.11 for parts, $91.80 for labor, and $587.91 total.22 Thus, dtiring the six-year period, average labor costs for repairs increased 1.3 percent, "crash parts" cost increased 114 percent, and total repair cost increased 82.4 percent.23 The effect of repair parts prices on overall repair cost and therefore on automobile insurance costs is obvious. This problem is compounded in still another way. Insurers and state insurance departments must attempt to predict the future effects of this inflation in establishing automobile insurance rates. The 1971 DOT report discusses various ramifications of these prediction attempts: ...The inflationary spiral has been the overri4 In anticipation of reduced expenses, because of the expected elimination of most of the negligency claims, the Massachusetts insurance department mandated a 15 percent cost-reduction in personal injury protection. However, the number of per­sonal injury claims, which had been expected to rise 30 percent, actually decreased by 34 percent. Profits for the insurance companies from this miscalculation were quite large-about "$50 million according to one source."5 In 1972, State Insurance Commissioner Ryan ordered a 27 .6 percent decrease in personal injury rates. "On top of that, motorists in 1972 got a govemment--0rdered rebate of about 26 percent on 1971 bodily injury premiums-an average of $12 per car-because no-fault was cutting costs of settling claims faster than had been expected."6 How­ever, although bodily injury rates were reduced substan­tially, "property damage coverage went up during 1971 by 38.4 percent over 1970."7 In the end, the total insurance bill increased as the benefits under no-fault d"creased (personal injury payments were limited to $2,000 _and 75 percent of wage loss payments, with the latter secondary to other wage continuation plans). On the other hand, rates in Massachusetts had been fro7.e11 for four years8 and insur­ance agents are quick to point out that "the collision and property damage rates would have gone up in Massachusetts regardless of no-fault. "9 A compulsory property damage no-fault provision was added in 1972. The three options under this proviSion apparently track those in the proposed Uniform Motor Vehicle Accident Reparations Act· (UMVARA) (see page .) The options are: • coverage permitting recovery without regards to fault; coverage permitting recovery only if the insured can show the other driver is at fault; • no coverage except protection against potential law­suits, which would be very rare. No record of the Massllchusetts experience under the 42 property damage law could be found for inclusion here. Florida Florida's no-fault law, the second to become effective, inevitably has been compared with Massachusetts. Florida's law provides more no-fault benefits, including medical costs and 85 percent of wage losses up to a $5,000 maximum. Florida's threshold of $1,000 is higher than Massachusetts' $500. {In both states, lawsuits are also permitted where death, dismemberments, disfigurement, loss of certain bodily functions, or certain fractures occur). One of the first analyses of the results of Florida's no-fault law was done by Joseph W. Little.Io He divided data from the claims files of two Florida insurance companies into two subsamples: (1) an exhaustive sample containing every closed personal injury claim, and (2) a major cases sample containing only the more serious cases. The data from both samples indicated the anticipated redistribution of the types of claims filed. The pre-no-fault split where tort cases were at least half of the claims gave way to a situation where tort cases were only 5 to 15 percent of the total (the 15 percent applies to the major cases sample). First-party personal injury protection (PIP) claims greatly outnumbered the tort cases in 1972. Because all of the major claim cases had probably not been filed when the study was done, Mr. Little was unable to evaluate the impact of no-fault on the courts. However, from the data available, no-fault evidently produced some of the desired effects. The time delay between a crash and initial receipt of benefit payments was shortened, which suggests more economy in processing, as does reduction in the presence of lawyers from the process."I I Obviously, however, this analysis was written too soon after the institution of no-fault to allow definitive conclusions. A later and more revealing study was made by the Automobile Insurance Study Section of the American Risk and Insurance Association. Insurers representing about 65 percent of the Florida private passenger automobile insur­ance market supplied incurred accident-year experience for 1971 and 1972 for the study. The results of this study indicated that while Massachusetts experienced a 52 per­cent reduction in pure premiums (i.e., accident costs) after introduction of no-fault automobile insurance, Florida actually experienced a 10 percent increase. I 2 The reason for this, according to the authors, is that while the reduction in tort claim frequencies, 71 percent in Florida and 75 percent in Massachusetts, were quite similar, Florida's reduction produced a savings of only 24 percent over the preceding year's incurred dollar losses. I 3 This savings was inadequate to finance the add-on benefit costs provided by PIP amounting to 42 percent of the prior year's losses. One of the reasons for the large increase in add-on benefit costs is that Florida experienced a 15 percent increase in drivers covered by insurance under the Experiences of Other States new law (Massachusetts experienced only a 3 percent increase since insurance was compulsory even before the ­no-fault law). I 4 There are several shortcomings in the Association study, some admitted, some not, which are important in weighing the impact of the results. First, medical payments insurance was completely ignored. Bodily injury claims before no­fault were compared to bodily injury and PIP claims after. Many individuals, however, surely carried medical payments insurance before the no-fault law and dropped it when they were required to carry the PIP coverage, just as they have in Texas. Consequently, the net increase in claims payments would not have been as large as the Florida study suggested. In fact, neither total-claims frequency nor average-claims cost would have varied to the extent indicated had medical payments coverage been included. The study also ignored the subject of expense ratios. A 71 percent decrease in tort-claim frequencies could result in lower claims-adjustment costs and thus lower expense ratios. Only the loss portion of the premium dollar was considered in the study. Possible reductions in overall plaintiff lawyers' fees and resultant increases in net benefits to injured victims was another factor that was not considered in the study. Even if, all factors considered, there was a IO percent increase in premiums after no-fault was enacted, there might also be a 20 percent increase in net benefits received by injured victims. In that case, actual cost would not have increased, but decreased, in terms of benefits purchased. This subject is considered in more detail in the next chapter. There was no mention of other variables that might have affected the Florida results. Changes in other laws affecting automobile accidents-Le., comparative negligence, guest statutes-or in driving habits were not discussed. The question thus remains: were the changes in claim frequency and severity detailed by the study attributed solely to the no-fault law or were other factors important? Finally, the findings were derived from a sample representing only 60 percent of the total market. Further­more, experience was gathered after the no-fault plan was in effect only 15 months. The diversity of forms, rates, statistical plans, and reporting agencies made the collection of a body of reliable data very difficult, prompting the authors to conclude that ''while the findings reported in the following exhibits are probably quite credible so far as the direction of change is concerned, the extent of indicated change is subject to the caveats implied by the lack of definitive, fully developed data."I 5 A common deficiency which has become evident during the conduct of this study-lack of satisfactory data in the area of automobile insurance-is further pointed out by the authors in their final conclusions. "Perhaps the experience in both states (Massachusetts and Florida) will ultimately illustrate that the quasi-science of no-fault cost prediction 43 requires a much larger and broader data input than that which currently can be provided by the statistical resources of insurers and state motor vehicle departments." 16 New York The New York no-fault law has not been in effect long enough to yield any conclusive results; however , there have been some interesting events associated with its implemen­tation. To insure that the move to no-fault brought about substantial savings in the prices paid by New Yorkers for personal injury insurance , the no-fault legislation contained a requirement that certain rate reductions be made at the inception of the new no-fault system. For basic no-fault plus $10,000/$20,000 (10/20) bodily injury liability, the legislature mandated at least a 15 percent reduction from the rates paid for 10/20 bodily injury plus $1,000 medical payments under the tort liability system. The statute also required an additional 5 percent reduction in the case of a person who opts for the $200 no-fault family deductible. The average rates approved by the Insurance Board and implemented February 1, 1974, provided an average re­duction in rates for basic no-fault plus 10/20 bodily injury of 19.2 percent. For private passenger cars, the average rate reduction was 18.2 percent. For commercial vehicles, the reduction was somewhat larger. In the case of those persons electing the $200 deductible, average reduction came to 24 percent. Recently, however, Policy Research Project participants were informed that the New York Insurance Board had approved a rate hike. It is not yet clear whether that hike provided for an increase in total premium rates or on the rates paid for no-fault coverage. In the final analysis, of course, actual claims experience will determine the rates and not the desires of the legislature or insurance depart­ment. Summary The record of actual experience with no-fault auto­mobile insurance is slow in coming and complicated and often incomplete when available. The limited experience of three states has been reviewed. That in other states has not yet been recorded or researched. One problem in researching the actual experience in other states is that, while figures and statistics are fre­quently used by both proponents and opponents of no-fault, both sides generally neglect to present the entire statistical story. Instead, each quotes only those statistics which favor its point of view. Also, it is interesting to note that, although no-fault proponents suggest four or five benefits which will be derived from no-fault laws-with the emphasis on compensation for all victims-the over­whelming concern in most discussions appears to be the possible cost savings. State Insurance Commissioner Ryan of Massachusetts wrote in 1971 that "for the most part legislative support (of no-fault) depended on a single factor-the hope, since established as a fact, that the plan would cut automobile insurance costs."1 7 FOOTNOTES I Calvin H. Brainard, "Florida; Land of Rising Costs in No-Fault", Trial , published by the American Trial Lawyers Association, 10:31 ff, January-February, 1974. 2Kentucky Legislative Research Commission, Legislative . Hearing, No-Fault Insurance, Informational Bulletin No . i 103, Frankfort, Kentucky, August, 1973, p. 79. 3state Farm Insurance Co., "A Watershed Year for No-Fault", State Farm Year, 1972, p. 28. 4American Mutual Insurance Alliance, "Focus on No­Fault in 1973" , Journal of American Insurance, Winter, 1972, p.31. 5Paul Gillespie and Miriam Klipper,No-Fault; What You Save, Gain, and Lose with the New Auto Insurance, New York: Praeger, 1972, p. 101. 6"How No-Fault Works in Two States'', U.S. News and World Report, volume 74, number 11, March 12, 1973, p. 40. 7Gillespie and Klipper, p. 95. 8Texas Association of ~urance Agents, National No­Fault Conference, July 22~23, 1971 , remarks by William Donahue, p. 46. 9Kentucky Legislative Research Commission, p. 79. lOJoseph W. Little, "How No-Fault is Working In Florida"; American Bar Association Journal, volume 59, September, 1973, pp. 1020-1024. 11 Little, p. 1023. 44 12Calvin H. Brainard, and John F. Fitzgerald, "First Year Cost Results Under No-Fault Automobile Insurance; a Comparison of the Florida and Massachusetts Experience," Journal ofRisk and Insurance, 41: March, 1974, p. 37. This ten percent increase occurred while a 15 percent mandated rate decrease was in effect, causing an extraordinary jump in loss ratios and thus a disasterous year for many insurers. See Bests Executive Data Service 1974 and Bernard L. Webb, "The Consumer's Interest in National No-Fault Automobile Insurance", a statement submitted for the Congressional subcommittee hearings on S.354, July 25, 1974, for comment. Experiences of Other States 13Brainard, March, 1974, pp., 36-37. l4Jbid, p. 37. l5fbid, p. 31. l6Jbid, p. 38. 17American Bar Association Journal, volume 57, p. 431. 45 CHAPTER. v PROSPECfS FOR TEXAS In previous chapters we have examined the theory of no-fault automobile insurance, several of the problem areas surrounding its implementation, and the limited experience of a few states which have enacted such laws. This leads us to several important questions concerning the applicability of no-fault automobile insurance to Texas drivers: How did Texas accident victims fare in recovering their losses under the system existing prior to September, 1973? What are the likely effects of recent changes in the law with respect to the ability of injured parties to collect and the cost of automobile insurance? What are the likely costs and benefits of a no-fault law for Texans? · CHARACTERISTICS OF THE TEXAS SYSTEM Before analyzing the possible impact of a no-fault law on Texas drivers, the similarities and differences between the Texas situation and that in other states should be exam­ined. Is Texas experiencing the same problems in the same degree as other states? Can the actual experience of states with no-fault laws be readily projected to the Texas situation? To find answers to these and similar questions, a survey was made from a randomly selected group of individuals who had suffered injuries in accidents. Next, primary data concerning Texas drivers and their insurance were collected from various state agencies. Finally, those parts of previous studies which dealt specifically with Texas were examined. It should be mentioned that the system examined here is the one in existence before the fall of 1973, when several changes in the law became effective. Texas Accident Survey For the survey, approximately 1,100 names were drawn at random from the microfilmed accident files of the Department of Public Safety in Austin. Only those persons who reported injuries in the calendar year 1971 were selected, because these cases would probably have had sufficient time to complete delayed claims settlements of litigation. Of the 1,100 questionnaires sent, 146 were returned with no forwarding address, and so were not deliwred. Another eight questionnaires were returned reporting the person addressed had sustained no injwies. Only 153 persons who had been injured responded and many of these responses were incomplete, with several questions left unanswered in most instances. Therefore, we cannot draw conclusive, statewide generalizations from the data pre­sented here, primarily because of the small sample necessi­tated by available research resources and because of the limited answers on many of the questionnaires which were returned. However, some interesting insights are afforded by the responses. The survey questionnaire was basically modeled after that designed for the Department of Transportation's 1969 nationwide study of automobile insurance. Some variations should be noted. For example, in the final question, which seeks a statement of preference between two types of insurance systems, no mention was made of the term ''no-fault" because of the emotional connotation, both pro and con, derived from ·it. Instead, two different systems were descnbed without labeling either of ~-The questionnaire is reproduced in Appendix B. While no attempt is made to apply universal validity to the resulting data, some of the calculations nonetheless indicate a reasonably close approximation to figures derived from the larger more comprehensive study conducted by the OOT. For instance, 843 percent of sample respondents carried liability insurance at the time of their accidents. OOT and Texas Department of Public Safety figures ' indicate approximately 79 percent of Texas drivers are covered by liability insurance. Promptneu ofClaim Settlement It has been argued that insurance systems under tort liability are inefficient because settlement of claims by insurance companies takes much longer than necessary. From the survey, which compared the total amount of claims with time needed for settlement, larger claims are shown to take longer for settlement than smaller claims. Since only 45 of the 153 responses could be cross­tabulated, these figures are hardly conclusive, but 14 of 23 46 or 60.9 percent of the claims for more than $1 ,000 took more than 30 days to settle. Eighty percent of the claims for less than $500 were settled in less than 30 days. Adequacy ofClaim Settlement Another criticism of the current system is that large Prospects for Texas claims are undercompensated and smaller claims are over­compensated. To test the applicability of this statement to Texas drivers, responses giving the amounts of total loss experienced were cross-tabulated with responses specifying the amounts received in settlement from insurance com­panies. Here is a summation of the survey results describing levels of compensation: j TABLE V-1 AMOUNT RECENED FROM AT FAULT PARIT Amount of Total Loss O 1-100 101-500 0 2 0 0 1-100 2 1 101-500 4 2 7 501-1000 6 0 2 Over 1000 1 1 1 ' 14 5 11 Since the questionnaire treated all amounts over $1,000 in one category, it is not possible to estimate the degree of undercompensation of large losses. However, it can be seen from this table that smaner claims were quite often overcompensated. Seven of 15 (46.7 percent) with losses amounting to $501-1,000 received more than $1,000 in settlement. Five of 18 (27.8 percent) of those with losses between $101-500 receive.d more than $500. Six more received less than $100, however. Noteworthy is the fact that of the 37 respondents who experienced losses between $1-1,000, only 9 received settlements in the same range as their economic losses. This suggests that the tort system tends to subsidize the payment of excess benefits to some victims at the expense of other policyholders. Court Congestion and Costs Court congestion and high legal costs are another Over 501-1000 1000 2 1 5 0 0 4 2 3 18 0 7 15 0 15 18 4 26 60 criticism of the tort system of automobile liability insur­ance. The bodily injury accident victim survey showed, however, that only about 22 percent hired an attorney. Lawsuits were filed by only 12.1 percent of the respon­dents. These figures represent percentages of a sample of individuals who received bodily injuries in accidents, regardless of fault. In fact, about two-thirds of these individuals said the other driver was at fault, and about one-third actually received payment from the other driver or his insurance company. By comparison, the U.S. Department of Transportation study of paid bodily injury claimants in Texas in 1969 showed that 28.9 percent were represented by an attorney and 8.9 percent filed suit.1 In those cases where attorneys were hired, however, claimants nationwide received an average of 72.7 percent of the gross payment wit!t their attorneys receiving the . 47 remammg 27.3 percent.·i (The Texas figures were 81.8 percent and 18.2 percent respectively , but the authors believe these figures to be incorrect due to some incorrect assumptions applied to the calculations.)3 There is little available information on the amount of court congestion in Texas, let alone the contribution of automobile liability cases toward that congestion. In February, 1973, the Texas Civil Judicial Council conducted .a poll of district and county judges and clerks to determine the impact of several matters of legislative importance, one of which was personal injury cases involving automobile accidents. Over 86 percent of all district courts and 80 percent of the 310 county courts responded to the poll. The findings showed that for the year 1972, 4.5 percent of district court cases and 6.7 percent of county court cases involved automobile accidents.4 It would be helpful to have such statistics as the length of waiting times until trial in various locations, the average size of judgement, and others. The DOT studies and our own survey do substantiate the opinion that smaller claims tend to be settled more quickly than larger claims. Consequently, it is probably the larger claims which are going to court. It appears then that if there is any serious degree of court congestion in Texas, the amount which could be eliminated by a no-fault automobile insurance system would be relatively small for two reasons: first, a relatively low percentage of court cases involve automobile accidents, and second, those that do are probably the large cases which would still be in the courts under most forms of modified no-fault laws. Public Opinion on No-Fault An atttempt was made to elicit preferences as to the most desired automobile insurance reparations system. In this regard , it must be emphasized that there are limitations in survey questions regarding reparations systems. First, the respondent may not understand clearly the way alternative systems work. It is impossible to give J1lOre than a cursory description in a questionnaire. Second, questionnaires themselves can be biased through the manner in which the questions are asked. Leading words can elicit desired responses. Third, the sample population can be insufficient or biased. The researcher has always to wonder how the non-respondents would have answered. Fourth, what people say they will do and what they actually do are not always the same. For example, they may respond that, given first-party benefits after an accident, they would not hire an attorney nor file a lawsuit .. However, when an accident occurs, they may actually do just that. Our survey, although carefully designed, is no less subject to these limitations than most others. The survey population consisted only of those individuals who had sustained bodily injuries in automobile accidents in 1971. While the number of respondents was too small for the results to be statistically indicative of statewide experience, the results are presented as an indication of one group's opinion. It is recognized also that there have been many public opinion surveys taken in the past several years regarding no-fault automobile insurance. 5 The latest was conducted for Sentry Insurance by Louis Harris and Associates and the Wharton School. 6 The interesting point is that results have varied from anti-no-fault to pro-no-fault with no clear indication of public desire. If the actions of state legislatures are any indication, the feelings appear to range from pro-no-fault if sizable premium savings are involved to apathy or anti-no-fault if no such savings are forecast. In our survey, an attempt was made to remove any bias either for or against the term "no-fault" by not using it. Instead, two systems were very briefly described, one an essentially pure no-fault system, the other a tort liability system. Since most no-fault laws are modified, retaining the tort liability concept, it would probably have been useful to broaden the question. But it probably would have been so complex and confusing as to nullify the results unless the questionnaire were made much longer and people per­sonally interviewed. Given a choice, then, between an essentially pure no-fault system or the tort liability system, slightly more than half of our sample of 148 said they preferred the "fault" system. About one~fourth said they preferred the "pure no-fault" system. Another one-fifth were not sure. There was no tendency for those who were at fault to prefer the "fault" system. However, the greater the loss, the greater was the instance of preference for the tort system. The Sentry Insurance National Opinion Study con­ducted 90-minute interviews with 2,462 individuals nation­wide concerning consumer attitudes toward automobile and homeowner's insurance. Their results showed that more than half wanted a no-fault insurance law.7 One-fourth opposed it. Interestingly, when the phrase "no-fault" was not used, even more favored an essentially first-party system.8 From these results, it is easy to understand why little credence should be put in opinion polls. (To further elaborate, the State Farm poll showed anti-no-fault senti­ment while the DOT poll showed pro-no-fault sentiment.) Rather, it is more important to judge a system by its merits and limitations and act accordingly. RECENT CHANGES IN THE TEXAS SYSTEM: IMPLICATIONS In August, 1973, several new laws became effective in Texas .which caused some significant changes in the 48 automobile tort liability and insurance systems. The common law doctrine of contributory negligence was abolished in favor of comparative negligence; the restrictive guest statute enacted years ago by the legislature was modified; and a first~party benefits package, labeled per­sonal injury protection (PIP) was made a mandatory coverage subject to rejection under private passenger automobile insurance policies.9 These laws were all pro­moted and supported by the State Bar of Texas as a response to criticism that the existing tort system prevented many injured victims of automobile accidents from re­covery of their losses even when the preponderance of fault lay with the other party. Comparative Negligence and the Modified Guest Statute The effect of the comparative negligence law is to permit recovery by an injured party against another as long as the fault of the other party is as great or greater than. his.10 Under contributory negligence, neither party to an accident could recover against the other unless. he were completely free of negligent actions. Under the comparative negligence statute both can collect if their negligence is equal. Otherwise, the least negligent party may recover from the more negligent party. However, in any case the damages allowed are diminished in proportion to the amount of nelgigence attributed to the party recovering. Thus, if two individuals each suffered $10,000 losses and one accounted for 40 percent of the total negligence, he could recover $10,000 less 40 percent, or $6,000. The other party would recover nothing. If both parties were equally at fault in the above situation, each would collect half of his losses. Under the new modified guest statute, a non-fare-paying passenger other than a member of the family may recover his losses from the negligent driver of the car. 11 Under the previous law, the passenger would have had to show gross negligence or reckless action to collect. There is no way to predict with accuracy the cost implications of comparative negligence and a modified guest statute. Two of the greatest harriers to effective research in the social sciences stand particularly large here. First, past data under one system must he used to predict future performance under another system. Even though other states' experiences sometimes cari be used, seldom are the situations comparable. Second, there is no way to hold all other variables constant while one ·is changed, as is possible in scientific laboratories. Thus, at best, we can only predict what would have been in 1972 if we had had a comparative negligence law. If we project into 1975, then somehow we would have to negate the effects of variables such as the petroleum shortage, improved highway and automobile safety systems, and even the guest statute and PIP. Prospects for Texas The most notable and thorough study to date was made by Cornelius J. Peck, Professor of Law at the University of Washington, in 1959 and published in the Michigan Law Review. 1 2 Professor Peck compared both claim frequencies and total insurance costs in states with comparative negligence with those in states with contributory negli­gence. First he examined the claims experience of insurance carriers in four states with comparative negligence rules­Arkansas, Georgia, Mississippi, and Wisconsin-and their neighboring states. The frequency of claims per thousand automobiles insured for both personal injury and property damage was examined. Professor Peck then concluded that "Analysis of these statistics leads to no conclusion, unless i; is that an effect of comparative negligence is not observ . able."13 In a similar comparative study of insurance rates, Peck concluded that, "It is possible to say once again that if comparative negligence does affect insurance rates, its effect is not great enough to be observable in the complex of forces acting on the rate level. Indeed, it would not have as much effect as rapid growth of population, increased urbanization, or change to a traffic program with the effective safety record of a neighboring state. Its effect if any, would probably go undetected in the rates and statistics of the insurance industry."14 The major limitation of Professor Peck's study was that he had to rely on a time-constant comparison of insurance rates or claims frequency and severity data for different states. The fact is that there are too many uncontrollable variables to accurately attribute higher rates in one state to one variable such as a comparative negligence law. The passage of comparative negligence laws in a few states in recent years has facilitated new studies taking into account variables such as the existence or non-existence of guest statutes, the actual judicial interpretations and thus prac­tices relating to contributory negligence, and variance in the costs and styles of living, among others, which were denied to Professor Peck when he did his studies. One recent study concluded that "the likelihood of any significant change in automobile liability insurance rates which can be attributed to a change to comparative negligence is slight," particularly, "where courts, attorneys, and insurers have previously settled automobile litigation cases on the basis of comparative negligence, even where contributory negligence is the law."1 5 These conclusions followed an investigatio~ of the comparative changes in claim frequency and severity following enactment of comparative negligence laws in two other states. Needless to say, there may very well have been variables at work in those states which make such results inapplicable to Texas. That same study also predicted an increase in rates of approximately 5 percent due to the modification of the guest statute. 49 Another unpredicted factor was the adoption, along with the comparative negligence and guest statute law, of a new rule of civil procedure16 that simplified the process of submitting special issues to a jury. The result of this change could tend to cause a higher frequency of awards. At present, there has been insufficient time to ascertain the results of any of these laws on automobile insurance rates in Texas, if indeed it can ever be done. Penonal Injury Protection In August of 1973, an act (House Bill 143) relating to mandatory coverage for personal injury protection and certain disability and death benefits under a policy of automobile liability insurance, was added to Texas' Insur­ance Code. The personal injury protection (PIP) coverage provides optional additional coverage on automobile insurance policies for medical expenses and wage losses up to $2,500 per person per occurrence due to personal injury. Both driver and passengers of insured automobiles are covered. The coverage provides payments from the insured's own insurance company for those medical expenses and loss of income resulting from automobile accidents. However, insurers must include the coverage in all automobile liability insurance policies issued unless it is rejected in writing by the insured. Thus, all policies will automatically include such coverage unle~ the insured informs the insurer that he does not want it. · PIP n. Tl'flditional Mftlical Payments Co~. The major differences between PIP and traditional medical payments coverage are: • The new coverage extends the period of covered . incurred personal injury protection benefits to three years from the date of the accident. Under most medical payments coverage, the period is only one year. • The coverage adds benefits for ln coverages for medical expenses and loss of income. The PIP law provides that PIP benefits are payable without regard to the fault or non-fault of the insured, and must be paid without regard to collateral sources of medical, hospital or wage continuation benefits. The only deduction or offset allowed is in the case of a guest who makes a claim against his host. If the guest recovers PIP benefits, which will have been provided because of the coverage furnished on the host vehicle, the host driver is permitted an offset in any liability suit to the extent of PIP benefits received by the guest. An insurer paying PIP benefits is not entitled to any rights of subrogation. Texas' PIP closely parallels the Maryland Automobile Insurance Reform Act passed in 1972, which became effective January 1, 1973. The Maryland Insurance Commissioner testified to the Texas Senate committee considering the PIP bill that such legislation, in his opinion, would reduce claims because it would deliver prompt payment of up to $2,500 of first-party benefits. U.S. Department of Transportation studies show that in 1969 96 . percent of all bodily injury claims could be completely disposed of for $2,500 or less_1 7 The implication is that motorists are less likely to involve themselves in litigation of third-party liability claims if they are promptly paid their wage loss and economic bills. "Pure" no-fault has been descn"bed as an insurance system with total tort exemption. Programs with varying degrees of tort exemption are, then, modified forms of no-fault insurance. PIP coverage provides protection with­ out regard to fault, but cannot be classified as a no-fault insurance system any more than the existence of medical payments coverage, comprehensive physical damage and collision coverage (all of which are paid regardless of fault) in a policy would qualify that policy ·as no-fault insurance. PIP Effect on 11Ulll'tllU% Costs. It is unknown at this time what effect PIP will have on insurance costs in Texas. Before the PIP law became effective, Texas' Insurance Board Chairman indicated that it would not be used in calculating Texas' insurance rates immediately because from a year to several years experience would be needed to set rates. The Chairman did express a belief that the plan will help reduce insurance costs in the long-run. The current rate for $2,500 of PIP is $22 for the IA classification except in Harris and El Paso counties, where it is $23. This 50 Prospects for Texas compares to corresponding rates of $15 and $16 for $2,500 of medical payments insurance. These rates are based on actuarial estimates, however, rather than experience. It will be several years, at the minimum, before costs based on actual experience will be ascertainable. Lower premiums for bodily injury liability insurance are possible from the institution of PIP in Texas, but only if certain conditions are met. First, a large percentage of the driving population would have to buy PIP coverage on a voluntary basis. Second, those injured in accidents would have to refrain from bringing a claim or suit against the other party, since there is no legal restriction on suits against the other party whether or not a person collected from your insurance company. No information is presently available whether these two conditions are being met. At the same time, of course, other factors are at work on the bodily injury premium-changes in frequency of accidents because of reduced speed limits, less driving, or related developments; changes in claim size because of the use of safety belts and other safety equipment, or increased hospitalization costs; the new comparative negligence law with the modified guest statute; and new trial procedures. Because of these other factors,. it will be difficult indeed to isolate the effect of the new PIP law even when the experience statistics are collected. · PROBABLE EFFECTS OF NO-FAULT AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE FOR TEXAS Two recent predictive cost studies have been made r regarding no-fault automobile insurance: the Milliman and Robertson study for the National Association of Insurance 1 1 Commissioners (NAIC) at the request of the U.S. Senate Commerce Committee, and the Institute for the Future study, conducted under a grant from the National Science Foundation. The Institute for the Future dealt with various potential long-range impacts of different no-fault plans. The model, which included some costs factors, projected results to 1984, based on various assumptions about changes in driving habits, safety devices, social income guarantee schemes, and similar social factors. The NAIC study was an effort to overcome a major obstacle to legislative progress on no-fault insurance in various states-the controversy over the cost implications of particular bills. In August, 1972, the NAIC decided to sponsor an independent and objective costing program and the actuarial firm of Milliman and Robertson, Inc. was retained to develop a computerized model capable of evaluating the cost implications of a wide variety of different no-fault proposals. The model was also to be designed to deal with state-by-state variations in automobile accident injury patterns and in the existing tort liability automobile insurance system. Early in 1973, the U.S. Senate Commerce Committee, which was evaluating Senate Bill 354, the proposed National No-Fault Motor Vehicle Insurance Act, requested the NAIC to "cost" the bill based on the experience in five states, including Texas. The contract between the NAIC and Milliman and Robertson, Inc. contemplated the costing of this bill. The Cost-Estimate Study The primary goal of Milliman and Robertson's computer model was to generate a single figure: the percentage increase or decrease in the average personal injury automo­bile insurance premium expected to result from enactment of any given no-fault bill.18 The main goal of the overall costing system was broader-to convey an understanding of the study and its conclusions as the probable cost implica­tions of the bill. Another goal was to generate useful information to facilitate analysis of the study arid of the bill.19 Basically the cost-estimate study postulates a distribu­tion of persons injured in automobile accidents. The cost of these injuries is evaluated for the two reparations systems­tort and no-fault-and total costs are then compared. Using a base of 100,000 hypothetical injuries, the study seeks to determine the average insured cost per vehicle of these irijuries under both the present and proposed insurance systems. It systematically determines which of the 100,000 injuries will be compensated and how much compensation they would receive under each reparations system. Six variations of S. 354 were costed (see Table V-2 at the end of this chapter). Injuries were classified according to various characteristics such as: (a) type of accident, (b) type of vehicle, (c) role of the injured person, (d) seriousness of the injury, (e) fault status, and (f) insured status. Compensable amounts were made to vary according to similar injury characteristics. Thus, by accounting for the important sources of variation in compensable injury frequency and average cost between present and proposed systems, it is possible to obtain an indication of the cost change associated with a particular no-fault reparations system proposal. Injuries are distributed by types aJl.d numbers of vehicles involved and by severity. The model then· determines to what extent these injuries would be compensated under the first-party benefit provisions in the proposed no-fault legislation and te> what extent under residual tort rights. The costing system also takes into account such factors as eligibility for first-party benefits according to vehicle type, percentage of vehicles insured, provisions of the proposed assigned claims plan, percentage of injuries in the state involving out-of-state vehicles, and percentage of injuries occurring outside the state. In addition to bodily injury liability coverage, the model 51 also recognizes the presence of uninsured motorist and medical payments coverages under the current system, and makes assumptions about the extent to which they will be continued under the proposed system (see Appendix V-1 at the end of this chapter). Changes , in loss adjustment expense levels are also taken into account. Sources of Data. The primary data source from which variations in injury costs and distributions were obtained was the 1969 closed claims study conducted by the U.S. Department of Transportation. Other injury frequency data were gathered from sources such as the Federal Highway Administrations' Fatal and Injury Accident Rates on Federal Aid and Other Highway Systems 1970, the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration's National Accident Summary File, the National ·Safety Council, and the National Center for Health StatistiCs. Results of the Cost Study for Texas_ The cost estimate study yielded the results illustrated in' Table V-2 for Texas. The figures represent predicted percentage changes in the average total automobile premiums, i:he average personal injury premium, and total personal injury premiums for different no-fault plans when compared with the tort liability insurance system in effect prior to August, 1973.20 The Milliman and Robertson firm cautions observers that the results reflect actuarial judgement and statistics applied to a computerized model. It recommends that the study results not be used except in conjunction with certain caveats expressly stated in the study (see Appendix V-2). For example, it should be noted that the costing estimates do not project costs by class of insureds or territory, but rather represent only a statewide average. The actual effect of a change to no-fault may vary considerably by class and territory, depending on benefit levels, tort limitations, and amount of subrogation or loss shifting retained. Analysis of the Milliman and Robertson Study Milliman and Robertson make every effort to warn against the use of its predictive cost results in the absence of the caveats listed. There are, however, some questions and criticisms of the study that have been raised by experts in the field of automobile insurance even in light of these caveats. The seminar had access to three analyses of the Milliman and Robertson study. Two of the analyses were contained in statements made to the Senate Judiciary Committee by two professors of insurance, Calvin H. Brainard of the University of Rhode Island, and Bernard L. Webb of Georgia State University. The third analysis was done by the Inter-Association Actuarial Group (IAAG) representing the American Insurance Association, American Mutual Insurance Alliance, and the National Association of Independent Insurers. Professors Webb and Brainard, and the Inter-Association Group emphasize that their criticisms are in no way intended to question the competence of the Milliman and Robertson actuaries; rather they serve simply to point out the potential weaknesses in the study. Data Base. Webb said that one of the greatest weaknesses of the Milliman and Robertson study is its use of statistics generated under the tort system as its data base.21 (See Sources ofData ) Webb asserted that the data sources lack crucial informa­tion concerning the real levels of economic loss and collateral source recovery under the tort system. This information gap, he feels , leads to an understatement of economic losses which would be incurred under no-fault. Webb also believes the DOT data overstates general damage payments under the tort system. The result of the use of these questionable data items is an overestimate of the cost savings under no-fault.2 2 In his statement before the Senate Judiciary Committee Calvin Brainard also expressed concern over the data base used by Milliman and Robertson. Statistics gathered by Brainard from two Massachusetts state authorities for the year 1969 show 33 percent more tort claims per 100,000 injuries than are reflected in the Milliman and Robertson data. Since the total estimated costs for both systems were derived by multiplying the number of assumed claims per 100,000 injuries by an assumed cost per claim, it is possible for even a small error to significantly affect the predicted results.2 3 The Inter-Association Actuarial Group in its review of the Milliman and Robertson study expressed concern about the death statistics used in the study. The death ratios which serve as a starting point for statistical inputs into the model are taken from data showing the split between rural-urban deaths for one year of accident experience. The Inter-Association Group suggests that more than one year's experience might offset chance variations which may have occurred during the one particular year chosen.24 Our own analysis has shown that the death ratios used for Texas are subject to question . Milliman and Robertson used a death ratio (fatalities as a percent of total injuries in all automobile accidents) of 2.1 percent for Texas while Department of Public Safety statistics show that ratio to be approximately 3 percent. Use of the Department of Public Safety statistics would significantly reduce the predicted cost savings of no-fault insurance for Texas. Actuarial Assumptions. The lack of a complete body of data forced a great reliance on actuarial assumptions. The Milliman and Robertson report states that "an important part of the cost estimating system is the process of making assumptions...to the maximum extent feasible, these assumptions are based on relevant data or other objective information, but actuarial judgment is also an important factor in some cases. "2 5 The Inter-Association Actuarial Group states that: The necessity of actuarial assumptions is not symptomatic 52 of indolence. Rather assumptions are necessary because, in many cases, no one has had prior occasion to make objective measurements, and because costing involves forecasts of how people and institutions will change their behavior in response to a new reparations system and a changing legal environ­ ment. It is important to remember that the way in which actuarial judgment is exercised in making assumptions can have a very important influence on final comparative results.26 The IAAG does point out, however, that an assumption which proves to be inaccurate can have a significant effect on the cost results. One such assumption could be the insured ratio. For example, Milliman and Robertson assume that the compulsory aspects of S.354 would have increased the insured ratio in Kentucky from 68.2 percent to 84.6 percent. This assumed change produced a 1 percent indicated savings while little or no change would have produced a 9 percent indicated increase in system costs. Variance in other assumptions which could have a great effect on the cost estimates are those concerning the distribution of fault in accidents, the psychological thresh­old factor (i.e., the willingness of those who have recovered their out-of-pocket losses to forego tort claims), and the tort propensity factor (the aggressiveness with which injury victims pursue rights of action in tort).27 Webb has questioned a nwnber of the Milliman and Robertson assumptions for Texas. He points out that in the actual calculation of the model, Milliman and Robertson asswned that first-party medical payments coverage in Texas totaled 24.1 percent of the payments under bodily , injury liability coverage for private passenger cars. Statistics published later by the State Board of Insurance indicated 1 that such medical payments losses are only 18.7 percent of 1 private passenger bodily injury losses. He further questions i the actual amount of medical payments shown in the model I and asserts that this amount "would only be correct if I private passenger bodily injury payments constituted 93.7 , percent of all bodily injury payments, including commercial 1 vehicles. The Texas publication (Board of Insurance Statis-i tics) indicates that private passenger bodily injury payments ! constitute only about 68 percent of the total."28 Correc-l tion of the Milliman and Robertson Texas calculations for i these two errors, according to Webb would drop the projected savings from 17 percent to 9 percent. Webb also questions the 15 percent average deduction for income taxes iii wage loss payments. He says that since S. 354 provided that 15 percent is the maximum deduction for income taxes, the average should be lower and therefore, the costs of no-fault higher. 29 ' Interpretive Differences. A major problem with no-fault_ . cost predictions is that they can be interpreted in varying .\ ways. Brainard refers to the use of statistics by no-fault proponents which show great increases in the number of persons paid and decreases in cost resulting from no-fault implementation as "statistical hypnosis."30 He states that Prospects for Texas total costs are actually greater but are spread over a vastly increased insured driving population. The costs saving, then, would result from the compulSory requirement in S. 354 and not from the no-fault concept itself. Brainard does not actively contest the projection that the number of persons compensated from no-fault could increase by as much as 100 percent. He does, however, protest the use of that statistic without the accompanying revelation that the average benefit paid to victims would 31 drop by as much as 40 percent. There are other instances of questionable interpretation which have aroused protests not only from critics but from the Milliman and Robertson firm itself. The Washington Star News of June 22, 1973, contained an article which many persons interpreted as showing a potential for 25 percent to 40 percent savings in total automobile insurance premiums from passage of no-fault law. A letter from Mr. Frederick W. Kilbourne, a Milliman and Robertson official involved in the study, to the Editor of the Star News claimed that the article was indeed misleading and that their projections referred only to the personal injury portion of the automobile premium and not the total premium.32 The State Bar of Texas also labeled the Milliman and Robertson predictions as misleading in a full-page advertisement published in the February, 1974, issue of Texas Monthly. 33 The Milliman and Robertson firm, however, should not be held responsible for such apparent misinterpretation, as it continually states that the findings are not to be used in the absence of the stated caveats. In addition, it readily admits that the lack of a complete data base makes their predictions "subject to a high degree of uncertainty as well as being very susceptible to misinterpretation."34 Relative Savings Among Driver Classifications. The IAAG points to a shortcoming in the way the cost estimates are stated. The Milliman and Robertson estimates represent an average for all vehicles on the highway-trucks, commer­ cial cars, taxicabs, motorcycles-and does not express the costs savings which will be associated specifically with private passenger cars. The general driving population, composed primarily of private drivers, would not realize the full savings estimated by the model and might, in some cases, experience a cost increase according to this actuarial group.35 Webb also points to the absence of a breakdown in estimates per vehicle class as a weakness of the study. In addition, he suggests that to project average savings statewide without consideration for rural-urban differences is misleading. Though savings may be possible on a statewide average basis, the rural driver may very well experience an increase in costs while the urban driver experiences a savings.36 Milliman and Robertson do, however, list the failure to incorporate territorial relativities into the model as one of the caveats. 53 Predictive Ability. The final criticism to be discussed here is the difference between the model's predicted results and actual results in the states of Florida and Massa­chusetts. The Report of the Senate Commerce Committee on S.354 (page 37) included a comparison of predicted and actual results : Massachusetts Florida Predicted Savings 15% 24% Actual Savings 26% 40% Brainard, however, discounts these dramatic savings levels. In Massachusetts, he says, the savings "was due almost entirely to the totally unexpected and, as yet, unanalyzed drop in total claims from 117 ,813 to 70,900, or by a 40 percent decrease. Paradoxically, far fewer persons collected under no-fault than under the preceding tort system. On the contrary, the predictive model shows for Massachusetts an increase of 39 percent in total claims. There would therefore appear to be some kind of serious aberration in the model's claim propensity factor." 37 In the case of Florida, Brainard asserts that the 26 percent savings is in the price paid by insured motorists and not the cost incurred by insurers. He suspects that the 26 percent savings is entirely attributable to legislative man­date and in no way reflects insurer's costs.38 Consequently it is only a short run illusory savings. Summary. The criticisms discussed here suggest that the Milliman and Robertson model is not a precise predictor of costs under no-fault. Because of questioned assumptions as well as caveats expressed by the authors themselves, the model must be used with great caution and with full awareness of its limitations in any attempts to predict costs under any proposed no-fault law. The value of the model should not be overlooked, however, simply because it has limitations. Perhaps the Inter-Association Actuarial Group expresses best the value of the Milliman and Robertson study: The model has been constructed in a professionally competent manner. The data sources used are probably the best available. We have noted several technical criticisms, and have called attention to the absence of separate cost estimates for commercial versus private' passenger cars as a potential source of misinterpretation. Without question, actuarial assumptions play a vital role in determining final cost outcomes. In some cases alternatives and equally supportable assumptions will produce signifi­cantly different answers. For this reason, the Group cannot categorically support all results obtained from the Milliman and Robertson model. Notwithstanding the limitations described and the tech­nical criticisms and comments offered in this review, Milliman and Robertson, Inc. has made a valuable contribu­tion to understanding the cost implications of no-fault automobile insurance. Not only does the Model provide a systematic first approximation of costs, but it also provides explanations in a way that promotes specific criticisms rather than vague expressions of general dissatisfaction. In short, the Milliman and Robertson Model provides useful if not always conclusive cost information.39 Proposals for Improved Predictive Systems The preceding section has detailed a number of criti­cisms of the Milliman and Robertson Cost Estimating Study. There are several suggestions offered · by Webb, Brainard and the Inter-Association Actuarial Group for improYing the Milliman and Robertson efforts. In addition, suggestions are made here for improving no-fault cost predictive efforts for Texas. Inter-Association Actuarial Group. The most extensive suggestions for improvement have come from the IAAG. lri their review of the Milliman and Robertson Model, the IAAG offers these suggestions: 40 1. In spite of an expressed caveat of Milliman and Robert­son, there is danger that the study results will be misinterpreted because of a shortcoming in the way the cost estimates are stated. All of Milliman and Robertson's cost estimates represent an average for the total mix of vehicles on the highways, including trucks, commercial cars, taxicabs and motorcycles. No separate expression of costs associated with private passenger as distinguished from commercial cars and other vehicles is made. Per­centage changes in average ·premiums may be quite different among these vehicle groups, particularly when loss transfers between companies are restricted. There is some reason to believe there would be a shift in insurance costs from commercial vehicles to private passenger cars under some no-fault bills. Moreover, the primacy of Workmen's Compensation benefits would reduce no-fault costs unevenly across these vehicle groups. 2. Beginning with the actual number of urban and rural deaths in a given state, death ratios are applied to allocate deaths by vehicle type and injury/death ratios are applied to allocate injuries by type of vehicle based upon the allocation of deaths. This is the basic process by which injury and death is distributed over the 100,000 injuries in the Model and the basic way in which state variations in injuries and death can be reflected. Splits between urban and rural deaths by state are taken from one year of accident experience. It is suggested that more than one year of experience be used because chance variation could affect the year-by-year splits, particularly in low popula­tion density states. 3. Milliman and Robertson's estimates of the number of death claims as a percentage of all claims under the present tort system do not track well with actual experience. The DOT closed claims study data showed that approximately one percent of all bodily injury claims involved death cases. However, in applying their costing model to the federal standards no-fault motor vehicle insurance act, Milliman and Robertson's projected death percentages for the present tort system were much higher, ranging from 1.6 in California to 2.8 in Kentucky . The discrepancy in the estimate of death cases can result in a serious cost error, particularly under legislation that provides substantial survivorship benefits. Calibration 54 of the model so that projected death cases better approximate actual experience seems indicated. 4. The ratio of general damages to total bodily mJury liability payments has an important influence on no-fault costs. The higher the percentage of general damages, the greater will be the relative cost savings from their restriction. Milliman and Robertson used the consolidated 19 state data from the DOT claims survey in spite of the fact that there are substantial differences in the ratio of general damages among the 19 states. They expressed the belief that differences among states were probably caused by chance since general damages can be quite volatile. The Group's analysis of the DOT data has produced evidence to suggest that there are real. differences in the ratios of general damages to total damages among states. To reduce the possibility of chance . variation, general damages associated with serious cases were parceled out; then the non-serious residual were compared with non­serious total damages by state. DOT DATA-GENERAL DAMAGES BY STATE Ratio Non-Serious General Damages to State Non-Serious Total Damages Michigan .47 Minnesota .52 California 53 Texas .54 Wisconsin .57 Illinois .60 North Carolina .60 Missouri .63 Ohio .63 Pennsylvania .63 Indiana .65 Massachusetts . 65 Georgia .66 Florida .67 New Jersey .67 New York .67 Connecticut .69 Colorado . 70 Washington .79 These data show that there are differences among the 19 states surveyed. Because these differences will have an effect on cost estimates in some cases the Group believes the Milliman and Robertson Model should give them some credibility. 5. Loss of Services-Subject to variation dependU. upon the no-fault plan being costed, the Milliman and Robertson Model shows roughly that 20-25 percent of those who are eligtl>le for no-fault benefits will receive loss of service benefits. Preliminary no-fault experience of several com­panies represented in the Inter-Association Actuarial Group shows that less than 5 percent receive loss of service benefits. The reason for the disparity may be because Milliman and Roberuc>n significantly increased the loss of service frequency actually observed from tort data, in anticipation of greater use as a specified benefit under no-fault. 6. Erosion of Medical Thresholds-There exists the potential to deliberately incur medical expenses sufficient to Prospects for Texas penetrate medical thresholds and acquire a right of action in tort. There is evidence that this activity is already under way in Florida. Perhaps an assumption similar to the Psychological Threshold Factor, although opposite in effect, should be included in the model to account for possible erosion of medical thresholds. Brainard and Webb. In their statements before the Senate Judiciary Committee, Brainard and Webb offer limited suggestions for nnprovement. Brainard suggests that the predictive efforts of a number of actuarial bodies might be pooled to provide for much more success than the efforts of a single actuarial firm.41 Webb recommends the incorporation into future predictive efforts of factors which will account for variations in insurance costs and driving conditions among rural and urban areas. In addition, he speaks to the need for variation between private passenger and commercial vehicles discussed earlier under the IAAG suggestions. 4 2 Additional Propo!lllb. Several suggestions for improving future predictive efforts for Texas arose during the course of this project. It was our objective to incorporate these suggestions into the Milliman and Robertson model and actually perform the computer runs to determine changes in the results; however, a number of factors prevented this. Discussions with Milliman and Robertson actuaries con­firmed our belief that these suggestions could, given adequate time and computer capability, be incorporated into the model for Texas and would provide improved predictive results: 1. Test effects of changes in data base by substituting actual data on the frequency distnl>ution of injuries in Texas . Module 8 of the Milliman and Robertson model creates a frequency table for injuries occurring within the state being considered. A table of 54 cells classified by vehicle type, severity of injury, occupant status, number of vehicles, and a fault status is created . The basis for individualizing a distribution by state is the number of urban and rural deaths reported in the Federal Highway Administration's Fatal and Injury Accident Rates on Federal and Other Highway Systems 1970 for the state under consideration. Injuries and deaths are distributed over 100,000 injuries by applying de~th ratios to allocate deaths categorically. These death ratios are developed mathematically using the number of urban and rural deaths reported for a particular state. For Texas those figures for 1970were: Urban Deaths -1,332 Rural Deaths -2,228 Milliman and Robertson justified using the split between urban and rural deaths as the basis for developing the frequency tables by stating that this is one accident statistic that is available for all states on a substantially unbiased basis. They stated also that rural versus urban seems to 55 explain the relative frequency of injuries better than any other available variable. While actual death statistics were used by Milliman and Robertson, however, its calculated death ratio-i.e., fatal­ities as a percent of total injuries-was not the same as that indicated in actual data provided by the Department of Public Safety. A copy of the input for Model B, supplied by Milliman and Robertson, rather indicated that a signifi­cantly lower death ratio was used as model input. This discrepancy reduced our confidence in the results. We also developed the capability of producing a more reliable table by using data provided by the State Insurance Board of Texas and the Department of Public Safety. It was our intent to use Milliman and Robertson's Modules A, C, and D, and replace Module B with its own program. 2. Test effects of changes in Texas Law-the original Milliman and Robertson system was devised when Texas had a contributory negligence law and a strong guest statute. As the Milliman and Robertson system's results began to surface, Texas had gone to a comparative negligence law with a modified guest statute and PIP. 3. Test effects of different No-Fault Laws-S.354 was broad and set minimum requirements leaving much latitude in terms of what may ultimately result. Differing threshold limits and benefit packages could be tested. (It is within the capability of the model to test these.) 4. Test the sensitivity of selective input parameters used by Milliman and Robertson and ourselves-137 values are input into the model. We planned to selectively test several to determine if a percentage change in any one parameter would significantly change the results. Module C accepts Modules A and B's output for calculation. Module C calculates the number of injuries generated in Module B for each frequency cell which will be compensated under each insurance system, tort and no-. fault, and combines them with the appropriate costs as generated in Module A to determine the costs for each cell. It was in Module C that the seminar planned to test the sensitivity of some of the most important input factors to the model, particularly those factors which further de­scribed the injury population, including insurance status (guest statute, insured ratios, etc.) and those which defined the extent of no-fault coverage (eligibility, subrogation, etc.). Unfortunately, despite extensive efforts and com~ munications with the Department of Transportation and the Milliman and Robertson firm over a period of several months, time and resource limitations prevented access to the computer model for the performance of the tests. TABLE V-2 S.354 COSTS UNDER BENEFIT AND THRESHOLD VARIATIONS* CHANGE IN AVERAGE TOTAL AUTOMOBILE PREMIUM** HT HL HN LT LL LN -5 -1 +4 -8 -4 0 * Variation codes are defined in Appendix V-1. ** Entries are estimates of percentage changes in the average automobile insurance total premium (personal injury plus automobile damage) payable per insured vehicle under the proposed no-fault system relative to the previous tort liability system. For Texas, the personal injury premium is approximately 35 percent of the total premium according to the Milliman and Robertson, Inc. study. CHANGE IN AVERAGE PERSONAL INJURY PREMIUM*** HT HL HN LT LL LN -14 -3 +10 -23 -12 +1 CHANGE IN TOTAL PERSONAL INJURY PREMIUMS IN STATE**** HT HL HN LT LL LN +4 +17 +33 -7 +6 +22 *** Entries are estimates of percentage changes in the twerage automobile insurance personal injury premium payable per insured vehicle under the proposed no-fault system relative to the previous tort liability system. The personal injury premium includes bodily injury liability, medical payments, and uninsured motorist coverage. **** Entries are estimates of percentage changes in total auto­mobile insurance personal injury premiums payable in the state under the proposed no-fault system relative to the previous tort liability system. Source: Cost Estimate Study of No-Fault Automobile Insurance, prepared for the U.S. Department of Transportation, Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Pasadena, California, November 7, 1973, pp. 9, 10, 11. 56 Prospects for Texas TABLE V-3 BILL PROVISIONS AND VARIATIONS VARIATION PARAMETERS AND DEFINITIONS BENEFIT LIMITATION HIGH LOW Wage Loss Maximum Amount $25,000 variable $15 ,000 fixed Services Maximum Period 3 years l year Survivors Maximum Amount $15,000 $5,000 THRESHOLD PROVISION TIGHT LOOSE Disability Qualifying Period 6 months 2months General Damages De~uctible $2,500 none CODE VARIATION DEFINITION HT High benefit level, tight threshold provision HL High benefit level, loose threshold provision HN High benefit level, no threshold prQvision LT Low benefit level, tight threshold provision LL Low benefit level, loose threshold. provision LN Low benefit level, no threshold provision Source: Cost Estimate Study ofNo-Fault Automobile Insurance, Prepared for the U.S. Department of Transpor­tation, Milliman and Robert~on, Inc., Pasadena, California, November 7, 1973, p. 14. APPENDIX V-1 MODEL INPUT ASSUMPTIONS 1) Rehabilitation provisions will add 7% to medical costs 4) The income tax offset provision will reduce gross wage included in the data base. Sections i03(16) and 109(c). loss costs by 15%. Section 208(b ). 2) Medical costs beyond $10,000 per claim will add 6% to 5) Medical expense and wage loss costs will be reduced 5% medical costs limited to $10,000 per claim. each by the offset for workmen's compensation. 3) Wage loss costs beyond $10,000 per claim will add 6% Section 208(a). to wage loss costs limited to $10,000 per claim, 6) Medical costs will be reduced 5% by social security and distributed as follows: other federal government program offsets. Section a) $10,000 to $15,000 3% 208(a). 7) Wage loss costs beyond five months of disability will be b) $15,000 to $20,000 1% reduced 15% by the offset for social security. Section c) $20,000 to $25,000 1% 208(a). d) Over $25,000 1% 8) State temporllfY. disability programs will reduce wage 57 loss costs for the first 26 weeks of disability as follows: a) California 50% b) Hawaii 50% c) New Jersey 40% d) New York 50% e) Rhode Island 40% 9) Replacement service benefits will be payable on a seven-day-week basis. I 0) No-fault survivor benefits are based on population mortality, are discounted at 5% interest per annum, and continue if needed until the decedent would have reached age 65. Section 103(32). 11) Residual liability death claims will be equal in amount to tort system death claims when payable. Section 206(a)(5)(A). 12) Inflation has caused costs contained in the data base to increase by 25%. Section 20l(b). 13) State financial responsibility laws will not be changed and the average liability insurance limits actually purchased will relate to the minimum limits as follows: a) $ 5,000 minimum -$10,000 average b) 10,000 minimum -20,000 average c) 15,000 minimum -25,000 average d) 20,000 minimum -28,000 average e) 25,000 minimum -30,000 average 14) Persons with nonserious injuries yet eligible to take tort action will do so 75% of the time with no threshold, 85% with a loose threshold, and 95% with a tight threshold. Section 206(a). · 15) Persons with nonserious injuries and technically in­eligible to take tort action will qualify subjectively to do so 5% of the time with a tight threshold and 10% with a loose threshold. Section 206(a). I 6) A six-month disability threshold is equivalent to an average $2,000 medical cost threshold, and a two­month to an average $600 medical cost threshold, in each case varying by medical cost levels in the state. Section 206(a)(5)(B). I 7) The $2 ,500 general damages deductible will be 50% effective and will operate as a $1 ,250 deductible per claim. Section 206(a)(5). 18) A tort propensity will cause not-at-fault bodily injury claims to be increased beyond data base indications as follows : a) Connecticut 15% b) Illinois 10% c) Massachusetts 25% d) New Jersey 10% e) New York 15% 19) Mild guest statutes will permit tort action by a passenger 30% of the time, and strong ones 7*% of the time. 20) Out-of-state accidents and accidents involving out-of. state cars will occur with frequencies shown in Exhibit E-7. 21) Motorcyles will be included among compulsory cover­age vehicles under the law. Section 103(17). 22) The compulsory nature of the law will cause owners of half of the currently uninsured vehicles to purchase insurance, except in states where tort liability coverage is already compulsory. Section 104(d). 23) Loss adjustment expenses will change from 19% under the current system to 25% for general damage claims, 10% for death claims, and amounts varying by thresh· old provision as follows for no-fault and excess liability claims: a) Tight 11% b) Loose 13% c) None 15% 24) Administrative and marketing expenses will remain constant as a proportion of total premiums. 25) Bill provisions tending to increase insurance company operating expenses or claim payments will not be administered so liberally as to cause appreciable pre­mium increases. APPENDIX V-2 CAYEATS PERTAINING TO NUMERICAL RESULTS (Milliman and Robertson Cost-Estimate Study) Although the conclusions presented in this report are probably the best estimates available , it should nonetheless be recognized that they are subject to a high degree of uncertainty as well as being v~ry susceptible to misinterpre­tation. It thus becomes eSsential to specify that those conclusions neither be used nor released except in conjunc­tion with a thorough understanding of the following caveats: 58 (1) Average premium change indications will not apply uniformly, but rather will vary considerably by type of vehicle insured. Inclusion of motorcyclists under the no-fault law, for example, may be expected to increase premiums greatly for this group of motorists. (2) The study did not deal with changes in rating classifica­tion and territorial relativities, which may be substan­tial. Generally speaking, urban areas of a state may be expected to experience results that are more favorable than shown, and rural areas results that are less favorable. (3) The cost implications of the input assumptions and supporting data base to the model should not be overlooked nor underestimated. This is particularly true where there is a combination. of uncertainty and cost impact, such as of psychological factors affecting tort action rates and of large first-party _loss projections based on sparse data of limited applicability to no-fault auto insurance~ (4) The study deals exclusively with the relativity between the proposed system and the tort liability system currently or most recently effective in the given state Prospects for Texas with costs for both systems projected to 1974 levels. No attep.tion has been given to possible inadequacy or redundancy of existing premium rate levels. (5) The study addresses the automobile insurance system only, and not the effects of changes in that system on other lines of insurance or public institutions or personal risk assumption. (6) The findings presented in this report reflect no more than an attempt to predict the relative cost implica­tions of passage of a particular bill, and not the effects of various other influences on automobile insurance premiums. Such influences are many, and include changes in automobile safety features, enforcement of driver ·standards, marketing and · administrative practices, public attitudes toward seat belts and drunk drivers, and general economic conditions, among others. Source: Cost Estimate Study of No-Fault Automobile Insurance, prepared for the U.S. Department of Transporta­tion, Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Pasadena, California, November 7, 1973, pp. 12 and 13. FOOTNOTES 1 u.s. Department of Transportation, Automobile Per­ sonal Injury Claims, volume 1, July, 1970, pp. 78, 123. 2Ibid. . 31n every state 8.5 percent of automobile bodily injury losses incurred was deducted as an estimate of medical payments benefits. In fact, in 1968, medical payments claims paid were 41 percent of total automobile bodily injury losses incurred (partially explitining why medical payments insurance is more expensive for Texans than for citizens of most other states). When this factor is accounted for in the DOT formula, then Texas . attorneys collected 28.6 percent-higher than the U.S. average-of gross pay­ments to bodily injury claimants, rather than 18.2 percent as indicated in the DOT study. 4"Survey of District Courts", Texas Civil Judicial Council, Press Release, March 16, 1973. 5see, for example, U.S. Department of Transportation, Public Attitudes Toward Auto Insurance and Public Atti­tudes Supplement, 1970, and Thomas C. Morrill, Vice President, State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Com­pany, Presentation Before the Senate Antitrust and Monopoly Subcommittee, December 9, 1969. 6The Sentry Insurance National Opinion Survey: A Survey of Consumer Attitudes in the 'U.S. Towards Auto and Homeowners Insurance, conducted by Louis Harris and Associates, Inc., and The Department of Insurance, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, January, 1974. ' 7Ibid.,p. 67. 8Jbid., p. 66. 9Vernon's Annotated Revised Civil Statutes of the State of Texas, art. 2212a, secs. 1,2; VACS, art. 6701 b, sec. 1; VACS, Insurance Code, art. 5.06-3. 1oyACS, art. 2212a, sec. 1. 11VACS, art. 670lb, sec. l(a). · 12cornelius J. Peck, "Comparative Negligence and Auto­mobile Liability Insurance," Michigan Law Review (Volume 58: 1959-1960), pp. 90-129. 13/bid., p. 110. 14/bid., pp. 123, 129. . 15Jerry D. Todd, "The Prospect for Automobile Insur­ance Rate Changes Under Comparative Negligence." Texas BarJoumal, December, 1973,p.1154.16Rule 277, Texas Rules of Civil Procedure. 17 u.s. Department of Transportation, Automobile Per­sonal/njury Claims,ivolume 1, 1970, p. 3b. 18Final Report Concerning the Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance, developed for the National Association of Insurance Commissioners, by Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Consulting Actuaries. August, 1973, p. 7. 19Jbid. 59 20Effects of the new Comparative Negligence and Guest Statute Modification Law, and of the Personal Injury Protection Law which became effective for Texas residents in August, 1973, are not reflected in study results. 21 Bernard L. Webb, "Cost Considerations Under the National No-Fault Motor Vehicle Insurance Act (S. 354)." Statement before the Committee on the Judiciary of the U.S. Senate. January 30, 1974. 22Webb, pp. 4-6. 23calvin H. Brainard, "Statement of Calvin H. Brainard, Professor of Finance and Insurance, The University of Rhode Island in Opposition to Senate Bill 354, The Federal No-Fault Automobile Insurance Act" before the Com­ mittee on Judiciary of the U.S. Senate. February 5, 1974. 24Inter-Assoc~ation Actuarial Group (IAAG), "A Re­ view of the Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance." November 28, 1973. 25 Mi!liman and Robertson, Inc., The Final Report Concerning the Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance, presented to the N.A.I.C. Executive Committee, August 31, 1973, p. 12. 26IAAG, pp. 3-5. 27 IAAG, pp. 3-5 . '18 "" Webb,p. 8. 29Webb,p. 9. 30Brainard, p. 4. 31 Brainard, p. 4. 32 Frederick W. Kilbourne, Letter to the Editor of the Washington Star News, August 1, 1973. 33 state Bar of Texas, "The State Bar of Texas lays it on the line about federal m>-fault," advertisement, February, 1974, Texas Monthly, p. 69. · 34Milliman and Robertson, Inc. A Cost Estimate. Study of No-Fault Insurance, prepared for the U.S. DOT, November 7, 1973. p. 12. 35 IAAG, p. 6. 36 Webb, pp. 13-15. 37Brainard, pp. 7-8. 38Brainard, p. 8. 39IAAG,p.10. 401nter-Association Actuarial Group, "A Review of the Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance," a report prepared for the American Insurance Association, National Association of Independent Insurers and the American Mutual Insurance Alliance, November, 28, 1973. 41 calvin Brainard, "A Statement of Calvin H. Brainard, Professor of Finance and Insurance, The University of Rhode Island, In Opposition to Senate Bill 354, The Federal No-Fault Insurance Act," before the Committee of the Judiciary of the United States Senate (Washington, D.c.February 4, 1974). 42Bernard Webb, "Cost Considerations Under the National No-Fault Motor Vehicle Insurance Act (S. 354)," i a statement before the Committee on the Judiciary of the ; United States Senate (Washington, D.C., January 30, 1974). 60 CHAPTER VI ALTERNATIVES AND CONCLUSIONS This study of the feasibility of a no-fault automobile insurance system in Texas, had two pnmary objectives: to determine what effect the implementation of a no-fault system would have on premiums paid by Texas drivers; to investigate what benefits would be gained or lost under a no-fault system. The first problem encountered was that of defining the term no-fault. There is no single system of no-fault insurance; rather there is a wide variety of existing and proposed no-fault plans. In order to ac~omplish the study's objectives, it was therefore necessary to consider these various plans both as they operate elsewhere and as they might potentially operate in Texas. The second problem encountered was a lack of reliable data upon which to base solid, unquestionable conclusions. The relative newness of the no-fault plans currently operating in other states, the demographic differences between those states and Texas, and most frustratingly, the manipulation of statistics by both opponents and propo­nents of no-fault, all combined to make much of the available data either non-transferable or meaningless. Ex­treme caution, therefore, was exercised in the use of data throughout the report, and every effort has been made to warn the reader of the inherent weakness of our statistical analyses. Since cost is a major concern of those legislating no-fault plans, much time and effort went into the gathering of appropriate data for cost estimations. It should be realized from the start, however, that even should the enactment of a no-fault law produce significant cost savings, they would apply only to one segment of the total automobile insurance premium. Typically, that part of the total premium paid for property damage coverages (i.e., property damage liability, collision, and comprehensive) remains unaffected by no-fault laws. These coverages typically account for about two-thirds of the total premium. Consequently, "bottom line" premium reductions for individuals would depend on the percentage of their total premiums attributable to bodily injury liability and first­party coverages such as medical payments, personal injury protection, and uninsured motorists. In order to make cost estimates for no-fault insurance in Texas, the project relied on the Milliman and Robertson Cost Estimating Model for S.354, the proposed National No-Fault Automobile Insurance Act. In our opinion, this is the best model currently available for testing the potential costs of no-fault automobile insurance. Its reliability, however, is limited not only by the caveats that Milliman and Robertson cite but, further, by the vast array of actuarial judgments and data assumptions that are included in the m.odel. For example, Milliman and Robertson data estimated the fatality ratio (the ratio of deaths per 100 injuries) in Texas for all drivers to be 2.1 percent. Department of Public Safety data, however, showed the actual 197~ fatality ratio to be approximatley 3 percent while that for 1970 was even higher. The difference in these two ratios alone, when included in the model, would significantly increase the personal injury perrnium pro­ jection over that produced by the Milliman and Robertson calculations. Many other estimates and assumptions affect Milliman and Robertson's cost estimations significantly. For these reasons, we conclude that we cannot justify recommending a switch to no-fault on the basis of premium reduction alone. The more important question, then, becomes that of benefits gained · or lost as a result of a no-fault plan. In Chapter I the desirable characteristics of a good automobile insurance. system are listed. They include: (1) It should compensate a maximum number of injury victims; (2) it should provide adequate and just compensation; (3) it should pay benefits promptly; (4) it should be economi­ cally efficient-Le., return a high percentage of total premiums to victims; (5) it should provide for correlation with other insurance; (6) it should guarantee availability of reliable coverage; (7) it should encourage prevention and rehabilitation; and (8) it should be easily understood by insurance consumers and providers alike. The benefits lost and gained under reform proposals will be discussed in terms of these characteristics and how these characteristics are or are not a part of the current tort liability system. Following much study and discussion, we have limited our reform alternatives to two plans; one, a modified no-fault system, and the other a modified tort liability 61 system. The features of the two plans are: PROPOSED MODIFIED NO-FAULT PLAN I. Compulsory first-party no-fault (PIP) with $2,500 eco­nomic loss protection minimum. 2. Compulsory liability coverage for bodily injury (I 0/20,000) enforceable by fines. 3. Automobile insurance primary. 4. First-party no-fault benefits are to be mandatory and are to be the initial source of loss recovery. 5. Subrogation of first-party benefits is to be allowed. 6_ Lawsuits are permitted for economic loss recovery over $2,500. 7. General damage lawsuits are permitted for loss exceeding medical cost threshold, or cases of dismemberment, permanent disfiguration, or death. 8. Duplicate payments from within the automobile insur­ance system are not allowed. 9. A penalty for delinquent payment of first-party benefits assessed against the insurer (1.5 percent per month after 30 days). PROPOSED MODIFIED TORT LIABILITY PLAN 1. Compulsory PIP with $2,500 minimum. 2. Compulsory liability coverage for bodily injury (10/20) enforceable by fines. 3. Automobile insurance primary. 4. First-party (PIP) benefits are to be compulsory and are to be the initial source of loss recovery . 5. Subrogation of first-party benefits is to be allowed. 6. Lawsuits for economic losses are permitted only for amounts in excess of $2,500. 7. Lawsuits for general damages are unrestricted. However, in such suits the "Delaware evidentiary rule" will apply. Under this rule damages for which compensation is available under required first party coverages is inadmis­sible evidence. 8. Duplicate payments from within the automobile insur­ance system are not allowed. 9. A penalty for delinquent payment of first-party benefits assessed against the insurer (1 .5 percent per month after 30 days). Compensation to Victims Weaknesses in present financial responsibility laws in many cases allow innocent victims in automobile accidents to go totally without compensation for their losses. Furthermore , unless the at-fault drivers have purchased first-party automobile coverage, they receive no compensa­tion for their losses. If they have not purchased such first-party automobile coverage, they must rely on other forms of insurance or personal resources to cover their losses. Ultimately, we believe that a good automobile insurance system should seek to assure that all automobile accident victims receive compensation for their losses. For this reason, first-party coverage should be made compulsory regardless of whether the reform plan chosen is an improvement of the tort liability system or a modified no-fault plan. Under the proposed modified no-fault plan described here, beyond compulsory first-party coverage of $2,500, residual liability coverage should be required up to at least the present 10/20 bodily injury limits. Serious considera­tions should be given to raising these limits to bring them more in line with current costs and inflationary trends. The improved tort liability system would also feature both compulsory first-party (PIP) and tort liability cover­age. The requirement that PIP be the initial source of recovery for economic losses under PIP limits would, in many cases, make tort liability coverage residual (i.e., applicable only when losses are above $2,500) as in the case of modified no-fault. The difference between this system and the modified no-fault plan is that in those instances where suits are filed for pain and suffering, tort liability coverage becomes the primary provider of benefits. In summary, our belief that an insurance system should ideally seek to compensate as many accident victims as possible prompts the conclusion that both first-party and residual tort liability benefits should be made compulsory. Such a requirement should provide adequate coverage in most automobile injury cases. Since a compulsory insurance requirement will not likely result in 100 percent of Texas' drivers purchasing (PIP) and liability coverage, however, there will still be some innocent victims of uninsured motorists who will go uncompensated for their losses. However, uninsured motorist coverage is available for such cases. To the extent that compulsory liability is successful in increasing the percentage of insured motorists, the already minimal uninsured motorist premium should de­crease even further. Adequate and Just Compensation In Chapter I it was stated that an insurance system should seek not only to compensate as many victims as possible, but also to compensate them adequately and justly. The U.S. Department of Transportation closed claims study as well as our own survey showed that small losses are often overcompensated. Both the modified no-fault and the modified tort plans would provide more adequate and just compensation. Overcompensation of accident victims is said to be caused by the threat of suit for pain and suffering. A modified no-fault plan would not allow a victim to sue for pain and suffering unless he first incurs a certain amount of medical expenses. Consequently, in those cases where the victim does not exceed the medical expense threshold, the 62 Alternatives & Conclusions threat is removed. For such a plan to be effective, this threshold must not be too low, however, for in that case there is an incentive for claimants to overutilize or even fake medical services to get above the threshold. The same circumstances would surround a claim filed for PIP benefits under the modified tort system. However, under that system the victim can still seek tort remedy for general damages. As far as undercompensation of large losses is concerned, neither modified no-fault nor modified tort liability could drastically change the present trend. Difficulties in mea­suring large on-going losses, reluctance of juries to make adequate settlement, contingency fee arrangements and inadequate insurance limits will continue to cause under­compensation. Quick Delivery ofBenefits Another area in which the tort system falls short of the desirable characteristics of an automobile insurance repara­tions system is the delay in the delivery of benefits to accident victims. Both the modified no-fault plan and the modified tort liability plan would provide speedier delivery of benefits for out-of-pocket econo.mic losses through first-party payments, penalties for delinquency in payment, and expected reduction in time-consuming tort actions. The higher the threshold, the lesser the number of tort actions allowed in the system, and, therefore, the greater the number of claims settled quickly. This does not, however, speak to the adequacy and fairness of those benefits. Economic Efficiency­ Retum on Premium Dollar One of the major criticisms of the' current automobile insurance system is the apparent waste involved in the delivery of benefits to injury victims. Natipnwide, only 42 cents out of each bodily injury premium dollar finds its way back into the hands of claimants and only 14 cents of this is for non-duplicated out-of-pocket costs, according to estimates made by the U.S. Senate Antitrust and Monopoly Committee. While data specifically for Texas was unavail­able, the total nationwide bodily injury premiums dollar breakdown is :1 Return to claimants Pain and Suffering Duplicative Coverage Economic Benefits Legal Costs Plaintiff Lawyers Court Costs Adjustment Costs Company Expenses (Sales, Overhead, Taxes) .42 .21 .07 .14 .18 .16 .02 .14 .26 TOTAL $1.00 Return on premium dollars for health insurance and particularly group insurance and social security are con­siderably higher. So, when defining economic efficiency strictly from the standpoint of percentage return to victims per premium dollar paid into the system, automobile bodily injury liability insurance is not as efficient as the above forms of first-party insurance. No-fault proponents argue that their system of first­party payments could more closely approach the efficiency levels of other first-party coverages. Assume, for instance, that the modified no-fault plan described earlier had a threshold which would eliminate one-half the dollars presently going to legal expenses. The exact dollar amount of this threshold is not important provided it would eliminate one-half the legal expenses of the current system. The bodily injury breakdown stated above might be revised to show only 9 cents going to legal expenses while benefits returned might be expected to increase to 51 cents. Adjustment costs might also be expected to decrease somewhat with first-party settlements but such a decrease might be offset to a degree by allowance for subrogation. The modified tort-liability system would have somewhat similar results. The requirement that PIP be the initial source of recovery for economic losses below $2,500 would remove those claims for the tort system, thereby reducing somewhat the legal costs of the system. It would not, however, reduce the costs as much as the proposed modified no-fault plan because of the absence of any limitation on the right to sue for general damages. Co"elation with Other Forms ofInsurance Under the existing Texas PIP law, an injury victim can recover his own PIP benefits, and then recover tort benefits for the same injury claim from the wrongdoer. Such double payment is both inequitable and costly. Both proposed systems would alleviate this problem with their allqwance for subrogation by the insurance companies of not-at-fault drivers for first-party benefits paid to their insureds. Tort recovery by the injury victim for economic losses would be limited to those cases where losses exceed first-party coverage. There is also duplication of coverage between automo­bile insurance and other forms of insurance. Such duplica­tion works to increase the costs of both coverages and should be reduced or eliminated where possible. It is our conclusion that: the advantages of the current automobile insurance rating system should be preserved; that insurance which individuals are forced to buy should be the one which must pay benefits. Therefore, it is recommended that, under a system of compulsory automobile insurance, the automobile insur­ance benefits should be primary over other forms of 63 insurance, with limited exceptions, such as workmen's compensation and government-provided military benefits. If these existing governmental programs, which are cur­rently primary coverages, were made excess coverages, the cost of automobile insurance would rise considerably while employers' and the federal government's cost would be reduced . Availability ofReliable Coverage The ready availability of automobile insurance to all who need it has been a problem since the institution of financial responsibility laws, if not before. The problem is compounded whenever insurance is made compulsory, however, According to studies conducted for the U.S. Department of Transportation by one of the authors of this study, Jerry D. Todd, under the current system in Texas coverage is generally available even for the very high-risk driver. The Texas Automobile Insurance Plan and several county mutuals operating essentially outside the state's rate regula­tory system for automobile insurers assure accessibility to insurance markets for practically anyone seeking automo­bile insurance. The costs, however, are extremely high and tend to make such coverage unaffordable to many drivers. Only a very small percentage of the state's drivers are insured in either of these ways. A shift to compulsory insurance will likely bring a significant increase in numbers into the "high risk" market. Even the county mutuals are selective, and the assigned risk pool guarantees only liability insurance, not other coverages needed by motorists. Con­sequently, it is our conclusion that, at the minimum, the current assigned-risk plan should guarantee availability of liability insurance and PIP coverage to all motorists who cannot otherwise obtain necessary coverage from the voluntary market. Further study· is needed in this area to determine the best means of coping with the high-risk driver. Emphasis on Rehabilitation and Prevention Proponents of the tort system often claim that liability based on negligence is a deterrent to careless driving. It is argued that drivers will be more careless if they are not responsible for their actions. Furthermore, rating under a no-fault system, it is said, would penalize careful low-risk drivers while in effect rewarding the causers of accidents. Under either alternative proposed here-modified no­ fault or modified tort-the rating structure or classification system would remain essentially the same as it is now, based partially on driving records. Thus, those drivers who receive traffic citations and convictions will pay higher rates than those free of such violations. This solution is more equitable than the alternatives, and if such incentives are present in the driving situation, they will encourage safer driving habits. Adjustments are needed, however, because under this system, insureds paying the highest rates may not be the same as those receiving the most benefits. Likewise, insurers receiving low rates from a group of insureds may be forced to pay high benefits to them even though they are not at-fault drivers. The subrogation process permits such adjustment between insurers. While there has been no real evidence to show causality between the exposure to liability suit and driving behavior, if such a relationship exists the modified tort liability system would preserve it. The individual driver, in that case, is still fully liable for general damages. The existence of compulsory first-party benefits should increase rehabilitation efforts for two reasons. First, for both alternatives the incentive to prolong recovery is reduced. The insurer is in fact penalized if it delays payment. The insured is able to recover simply and directly the full amount of his economic losses. The need to negotiate a settlement based on probabilities of fault are reduced to those cases involving large sums. Second, by quickly disbursing funds to the insured and encouraging him to seek rehabilitation, the insurer is better able to reduce long-run payments and settlements. In some cases at present, immediate rehabilitation may actually be dis­couraged by the plaintiff's attorney on the grounds that it would reduce the amount of settlement. Public Understanding Either system, modified tort liability or modified no­fault, should prove easier to understand for the insured and provider than the present system, because of the stress of first-party coverage. When an insured is involved in an accident, the general tendency is to frrst contact his own insurer, which in fact, he is required to do in most cases under the conditions of his contract. In most cases, it should prove far simpler and more understandable for a policyholder to have his own insurer make restitution for his economic loss rather than track down the other party (which may be difficult itself in this day of widespread interstate travel), negotiate with his insurance company, wonder whether any settlement offer received from such insurer is a fair one, and whether to hire an attorney. Of course, in all cases involving serious injury, the insured will need to pursue these avenues for adequate indemnification. There may continue to be misunderstandings about what and how much is covered, in some cases determinable only by legal action against one's own insurer, but such cases are present in the current system and are likely to be present under any new plan. Along with public understanding, public acceptance is very important. If the amount of coverage required by law, for example, is inadequate or inequitable, increasing frustra­ tion and eventual lawsuits will result, making the system 64 less effective. For this reason, it is proposed that the required $2,500 PIP limits or whatever other limits are adopted be adjusted upward on an automatic basis as the cost of living increases. It is also suggested that the maximum wage remuneration be sufficiently high to allow at least two-thirds of the working population to recover at least two-thirds of their wages~ Again this maximum figure should be subject to automatic adjustment upward to overcome the problems that have plagued workmen's compensation claimants over the past decades. Optional coverages should make available increased limits. General Conclusions Having discussed all the characteristics of a desirable reparation system separately, it is now necessary to discuss them collectively by what we consider the most important overall standard of excellence-a high benefits/cost ratio. Other things equal, that system is best which produces the highest level of benefits in relation to its costs. ) Mention has already been made of the fact that no-fault automobile insurance cannot be justified on the basis of premiums reduction alone. But premiums and cost are not synonomous terms. If two individuals pay the same premium for different coverages, their costs are not the same. In fact, one individual could pay a higher premium than the other and actually have a lower cost, if his coverage were greater than the differential in premium. The concept of relative cost, then, is measured only in relation to benefits. If one dollar buys two units of some good or service while two dollars buys · five units, the second alternative is the more costly one in terms of absolute dollar outlay but is cheaper in terms of cost per unit. In fact, of course, both measurements are relevant to our analysis. However, to say that a proposed reparations system does not produce a premium reduction (often wrongly referred to as a "cost saving") is not to condemn it, especially where the benefits are increased while the premium remains fixed or where the benefits are increased by a greater amount than the increase in premiums. First-Party Payments. The principle of first-party pay­ ment of benefits has been emphasized and has many advantages. First-party payments provide compensation to more victims, delivers those benefits more promptly, and allows more efficiency in delivery of those benefits than does the present system. For these reasons, first-party coverage was made compulsory in both of the alternatives presented here. The $2,500 level of first-party coverage was chosen because currently the bulk of claims in Texas are for less than this amount and this would be paid under a prompt and efficient first-party system. Department of Public Safety data show that in 1973, 90 percent of all automobile injury claims were for less .than the $2,500. As noted earlier, this figure should be adjusted upward over Alternatives & Conclusions time to reflect changes in medical care costs and average wages. Compulsory Liability at 10/20 Level. While embodying the first-party principle fully, it is also felt that people should be responsible for their actions. Therefore, an attempt has been made to strengthen the concept of financial responsibility by including, under both alterna­tives, compulsory 10/20,000 bodily injury liability insur­ance, enforceable by spot-check fines greater than the cost of annual compulsory insurance premiums. Such a measure should cause only small administrative difficulties and would provide a strong incentive to obtain the minimum compulsory coverage. The required coverage, though adding some administrative worries, would strengthen financial responsibility, by reducing the likelihood of occurrence of an injury for which there exists no means of compensation, and would provide more adequate compensation of large losses. It has been argued that compulsory liability coverage would cause insurance premiums to increase because (a) more accidents would be insured and (b) accident victims, knowing that most drivers have liability insurance, would have greater tendencies to file suits. The requirement that economic losses under $2,500 be collected from first-party coverage should greatly curb any such increase in the propensity to sue for economic loss. As for general damages, the modified no-fault plan would eliminate general damage suits except in cases where medical losses exceed a designated threshold, dismemberment, permanent disfigurement, or death. The modified tort liability plan, while not restricting the right to sue for general damages does severely limit the ability to prove general damage losses. The evidentiary rule requirement, as practiced in Delaware, would disallow the introduction of evidence showing economic losses into a general damage proceeding unless such economic losses exceeded the specified thresh­old. Thus, the general damage plaintiff would be forced to document his pain and suffering in ways other than through evidence regarding extravagant economic losses. For these reasons, it is concluded that compulsion as recommended in both plans will not cause a great increase in the number of tort actions or a resulting increase in rates. It is fully realized that a compulsory insurance law will not bring about 100 percent compliance. In fact, according to New York's experiences, increases in costs and adminis­trative efforts to enforce compliance are not rewarded by proportionate increases in insured motorists, and even then 100 percent will not be reached. Consequently, there is still need for uninsured motorist coverage or optional higher­than-required PIP limits. At the same time, there are those who will be unable to afford the high cost of insurance. It was not considered a part of this study, however, to determine the solution to the age-old problem of what to do about those drivers of 65 limited means who would face considerable hardship in meeting their legal financial responsibility. Primacy. As stated earlier in this chapter, the insurance which people are forced to buy should be the insurance that is forced to pay benefits. In both alternative plans, it is recommended that automobile insurance be the primary source of recovery for automobile-related injury losses. In so doing, provision has been made for the elimination of duplicative benefits from different forms of insurance and allowance made for the internalization of automobile insurance industry costs. Mandatory Recovery. Provision is made for first-party benefits under both alternatives, and. it is also mandated that those benefits be the initial source of loss recovery. The first-party system of payment cannot function at maximum effectiveness without this requirement. Subrogation. The purpose of providing for subrogation in both plans is to derive two jtnportant benefits. First, subrogation of first-party payments would eliminate the double payment of benefits from both first-party and liability coverages which presently takes place under the Texas PIP law. Secondly, it will allow the present rating structure to remain relatively unchanged. Individual rates would continue to be based on the risk posed to the insurance company by the individual driver in terms of his tendencies to cause accidents. Restriction of Lawsuits. Both of the plans under consideration would limit the number of tort actions. The difference, of course, is in their allowance for pain-and­suffering suits. The modified no-fault plan severely limits the right to general damage action. The modified tort liability, however, does not limit this right, and under it injury victims may file suits for pain and suffering regardless of the circumstances of their losses, but their court cases are restricted by the Delaware evidentiary rule. Penalty for Delayed Payment. No-fault opponents argue that in the absence of the threat of suits for pain and suffering, insurance companies will not deal swiftly with their insureds. The provision for a 1.5 percent monthly penalty to be charged against the insurance company after 30 days should provide the incentive needed to offset the loss of the general damage threat. Other Issues. In investigating the broader and more fundamental issues regarding no-fault insurance, some lesser issues have been left to other researchers. They are mentioned here so that future policymakers will give them adequate consideration in structuring any proposed no-fault legislation or related bills. First, it has been claimed that the inclusion of commer­cial vehicles under a no-fault law would result in higher costs for private passengers and lower costs for commercial vehicles. At least one study has recommended that commer­cial vehicle owners foot the whole bill in accidents involving their vehicles to eliminate this problem.2 Drunken drivers, those in the act of committing felonies, and those intentionally causing accidents have not been given the same protection against liability suit that others have under some no-fault plans. It is argued that to expose them to full liability will discourage such actions. Under both of our proposals, no recommendations are made for this special class of drivers. Without a federal law, each out-of-state driver will likely have insurance which does not conform to the state law. This problem was not specifically addressed in the study, but is handled in other states typically by an endorsement which makes the policy conform to each state's laws when the driver is in that state. Summary and Recommendation. As we have discussed the features and respective benefits and costs of each of the two proposed plans, it is clear that in most cases the benefits and costs of the two systems are very similar. There is, however, one basic difference in their treatment of general damage suits. This study recognizes that real pain and suffering do exist and that recovery for such pain and suffering should be permitted. At the same time, the abusive overuse of this right should be discouraged. It is probably true that severe restriction on the right to recovery for pain and suffering, as provided for in the modified no-fault plan, would result in some cost savings, but it is doubtful that these modest savings justify surrendering the right to sue for pain and suffering where they legitimately exist. It is, therefore, the recommendation of this study that the modified tort liability plan be adopted for implementation in Texas. FOOTNOTES 1U.S. Congressional Record, 92nd Congress, 1st Sess., New York Insurance Department, February 12, 1970, p. 1971, vol.117,no. 22. 91. 2Automobile fnsurance ...For Whose Benefit?, State of 66 BIBLIOGRAPHY Books and Booklets Gillespie, Paul and Miriam Klepper. No-Fault: What You Save Gain and Lose with the New Auto Insurance. New York: Praeger Publishers, 1972. Green, Leon. Traffic Victims: Tort Law and Insurance. Evanston, Illinois: Northwestern University Press, 1958. Greene, Mark R. Risk and Insurance.3rd. ed. Cincinnati, Ohio: Southwestern Publisrung Co., 1973. Insurance Information Institute. First Party Auto Insur­ance. New York, July, 1973. Insurance Information Institute. Insurance Facts 1973. New York, 1973. Keeton, Robert E. and Jeffrey O'Connell. Basic Protection Plan for the Traffic Victim. Boston: Little, Brown and Co., 1965. New York State Insurance Department. Automobile Insur­ance . . . For Whose Benefit. A report to Governor Nelson A. Rockefeller. Albany, New York, 1970. New York Times Index, 1973. Prosser, William J. Torts: Cases and Materials. New York: Foundation Press, 1971. Rokes, Willis Park. No-Fault Insurance. Santa Monica, California: Insurance Press, 1971. State Farm Insurance Co. No-Fault Press Reference Manual. Bloomington, Illinois: Public Relations Department of State Farm Insurance Companies, September, 1973. State Farm Insurance Co. State Farm Year. Bloomington, Illinois, 1972. Texas Association of Insurance Agents. National No-Fault Conference; Transcript of Proceedings. Dallas, July 22-23, 1971. Texas State Insurance Board. Texas Automobile Insurance Rating Manual. Austin, 1973. U. S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Monthly Labor Review, March, 1972. Articles American Mutual Insurance Alliance. "Focus on No-Fault in 1973." Journal ofAmerican Insurance. Winter, 1972. "Auto Primacy: Pro and Con.;' Journal of Insurance, July-August, 1973. · Bishop, Joseph W., Jr. "The Validity Under the Constitu­tion of the United States of Basic Protection Insurance and Similar Proposals for the Reform of the System of Compensating Victims of Automobile Accidents." Con­stitutional Problems in Automobile Accident Compensa­tion Reform. A Department of Transportation Study. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. Brainard, Calvin H. and John Fitzgerald. "Cost Predictions for No-Fault Legislation: A Case of Statistical Hyp­nosis?" Insurance Law Journal, January, 1974. Brainard, Calvin H. and John Fitzgerald. "First Year Cost Results under No-Fault Automobile Insurance: A Com­parison of the Florida and Massachusetts Experience." Journal of Risk and Insurance, March, 1974. Brainard, Calvin H. "Florida: Land of Rising Costs in No­Fault." Trial Magazine, 10:31 ff. January-February, 1974. Brainard, Calvin. H. "Is Equity of Insurance Being Sacri­ficed?" Trial Magazine, October-November, 1967. "Can a State Abolish the Civil Jury?" 1965 Wisconsin Law Review, 103. Cowen, Lindsey. "Due Process, Equal Protection and 'No~Fault' Allocation of the Cost of Automobile Acci­dents." Constitutional Problems in Automobile Acddent Compensation Reform. A Department of Transportation Study. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. "How No-Fault is Working in Fforida." American Bar Association Journal, vol. 59, September, 1973. "How No-Fault Works in Two States." U. S. News and World Report, vol. 74, no. 11, March 12, 1973. Insurance Information Institute. "No-Fault Gets a Green Light." T'he Journal of Insurance. New York, July­August, 1973. Isaacs, Nathan. "Fault and Liability." 31 Harvard Law Review 951 (1918). James, Fleming. "The Origin and Development of Negli­gence." From T'he Origin and Development of Negli­gence Action. A Department of Transportation Study. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970. Jones, T. Lawrence. "The Case for Making Automobile Insurance Primary." April 27, 1973. Kilbourne, Frederic W. of the Milliman and Robertson Actuarial Firm. A letter to the Editor of the Washington Star News, August 1, 1973. Little, Joseph W. "How No-Fault is Working in Florida." American Bar Association Journal, vol. 59. September, 1973. 67 Malone, Wex. "Ruminations on the Role of Fault in the History of Torts." The Origin and Development of Negligence Action. A Department of Transportation Study. Washington : U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. Peck, Cornelius J. "Comparative Negligence and Automo­bile Liability Insurance." Michigan Law Review, vol. 58 : 1959-1968. Sands, C. Dallas. "Constitutionality of Automobile Acci­dent Compensation Reform by Federal Law." Constitu­tional Problems in Automobile Accident Compensation Reform. A Department of Transportation Study. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970. State Bar of Texas. "State Bar of Texas Lays it on the Line About Federal No-Fault." (advertisement) Texas Monthly, February, 1974. State Farm Insurance Company. "A Watershed Year for No-Fault." State Farm Year, Bloomington, Illinois, 1972. Todd, Jerry D. "The Prospect for Autombile Insurance Rate Changes Under Comparative Negligence." Texas Bar Journal, December, 1973. "The Views of the Chief Justice." Life, August 7, 1970. Studies and Reports Claitor, Jack. ''Memo on Automobile No-Fault." Texas State Board of Insurance, April 29, 1972. Haldi Associates, Inc. A Study ofHawaii's Motor Vehicle Insurance Program. A Report to the Hawaii State Legislature. Special Report No. 72-1. Honolulu, January, 1972. Health Insurance Association of America. "Group Health Insurance Viewpoints on Overinsutance." Group Insur­ance Bulletin No. 3-61. Prepared by a joint ALC-HIAA, LIAA study group. Chicago, November 30, 1961. Health Insurance Association of America. "A Study on Non-Duplication of Accident and Health Insurance Benefits." Group Insurance Bulletin No. 3-62. Prepared by a joint ALC-HIAA, LIAA study group. Chicago, October 22, 1962. Inter-Association Actuarial Group. ~'A Review of the Millman and Robertson, Inc. Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance." Prepared by an Inter­Association Group representing the American Insurance Association, the American Mutual. Insurance Alliance, and the National Association of Independent Insurers. Presented to and adopted by the three associations in a joint meeting in Chicago, November 29, 1973. Read into the hearings record of the U. S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary by Senator Philip A. Hart on January 30, 1974, in Washington, D.C. Kentucky Legislative Research Commission. Legislative Hearing, No-Fault Insurance. Informational Bulletin No. 103. Frankfort, Kentucky, August, 1973 . Life and Health Claim Association of Kansas City. "Coordi­nation of Benefits Can Help Keep Down the Cost of Health Care." An Attachment to the Second Report of the Industry Task Force on Coordination ofBenefits to Accident and Health Protection by the Sub-Committee of the NAIC. Life, Accident and Health Committee, November 13, 1970. Massachusetts Special Commission. First Interim Report Relative to Compulsory Motor Vehicle Insurance and Certain Related Matters. Boston, January, 1970. Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Consulting Actuaries. Final Report Concerning the Cost Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance. Developed for the National Association of Insurance Commissioners. Pasadena, California, August 10, 1973. Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Consultmg Actuaries. Sup­plement I (Program Specifications to the Final Report Concerning the Cost-Estimating System for No-Fault Automobile Insurance. Developed for the National Association of Insurance Commissioners. Pasadena, California, August 31, 1973. Milliman and Robertson, Inc., Consulting Actuaries. Cost Estimate Study of No-Fault Automobile Insurance. Prepared for the Federal Department of Transportation. Pasadena, California, November 7, 1973. Public Affairs Research Council of Louisiana.. No-Fault Insurance-A Reasonable Alternative? Baton Rouge, Louisiana, January, 1974. Senate Committee on Commerce. Report of the Senate Committee on Commerce on S.354. Report No. 93-382. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, August 15, 1973. Texas State Board of Insurance. "Texas Private Passenger Automobiles Insured for Bodily Injury and Property Damage Liability." Austin, July 1, 1973. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Compensation Study: Automobile Accident Litiga­tion. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Compensation Study: Automobile Personal Injury Claims. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Study; Constitutional Problems in Automobile Accident Compensation Reform. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Compensation Study: Economic Consequences of 68 Bibliography Automobile Accident Injuries. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Compensation Study: Motor Vehicle Crash Losses and their Compensation . A report to Congress and the President by John A. Volpe, Secretary of Transporta- Cases &rker v. Kidd, (Civil Appeals) 357 S.W. 490 (1960), no writ. Beaumont Traction Co. v. State, 122 S.W. 615 (1909). Bell V. Burson, 402 U.S. 535 (1971). Bjorgo v. Bjorgo, 402 S.W.2d 143 (1966). Blair v. Paggi, 238 S.W. 639 (1922). Bu"oughs v. Lyles, 181 S.W.2d 570 (1944). Castleberry v. Frost-Johnson Lumber Co.; 283 S.W. 141 (Tex. Comm'n. App., 1926). Central &M.R. Co. v. Moms, 3 S.W. 457 (1887). City ofDallas v. Trammel, 101 S.W.2d 1009 (1937). City of New Braunfels v. Waldschmidt, 207 S.W. 303 (1918). City of West University Place v. Ellis, 134 S.W.2d 1038 (Tex. Comm'n. App., 1940). Ex Parte Gamer, 246 S.W.2d 723 (1968). Ex Parte George, 215 S.W.2d 170 (1968). Ex Parte Sizemore, 8 S.W.2d 134 (1928). Ferguson v. Skrupa, 372 U.S. 726 (1963). Friedman v. American Security 90. of New York, 151 S.W.2d 570 (1941). Grace v. Howlett, 283 N.E.2d474 (1972). Green v. W. E. Grace Manufacturing Co., 422 S.W;2d 723 (1968). Illinois Constitution of 1970, art. VI, sec. 14. International & G.N.R. Co. v. Edmundson, 222 S.W. 181 (Tex. Comm'n. App., 1920). Lasky v. State Farm, Florida Supreme Court docket No. 42,856. Luse v. City of Dallas, (Civil Appeals) 131 S.W;2d 1079 (1939), error refused. tion. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, March, 1971. U. S. Department of Transportation. Automobile Insurance and Compensation Study: The Origin and Development of Negligence Law. Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1970. Manzanares, et al. v. Bell, McDonald and Lobban, Kansas Supreme Court docket No. 47,412. Massachusetts Constitution, part II, ch. 1, sec. 1, art. 4. Mellinger v. City ofHouston, 3 S.W. 249 (1887). Middleton v. Texas Power and Light Co., 185 S.W. 556 (1916). National Carloading Corporation v. Phoenix-El Paso Ex­press, Inc., 176 S.W;2d 564 (1944). New York Central Railroad Co. v. White, 243 U.S. 188 (1917). Nichols v. Park, (Civil Appeals) 119 S.W;2d 1066 (1938), no writ. Olschewske v. Priester, 276 S.W; 647(Tex. Comm'n. App., 1925). Pinnick v. Cleary, 271 N.E.2d 592 (1971). Railroad Commission of Texas v. Miller, 434 S.W.2d 670 (1968). Revised Civil Statutes of Texas, 1925, as amended. Articles 8306-8309. Rucker v. State, 342 S.W.2d 325 (1961). Shavers, et. al. v. Frank J. Kelly, Circuit Court for County of Wayne, State of Michigan, docket No. 73-248-068CZ. Stediium v: Kirby Lumber co.; 221 s:w. 920 (1920). Texas Liquor Control Board v. Jones, (Civil Appeals) 112 S.W.2d 227 (1937). Union Central Life Insurance Co. v. Chowning, 26 S.W. 982 (1894). White v. White, 196 S.W. 508 (1917). -Williizmson v. Lee Optical of Okllzhoma, Inc., 348 U.S. 483 (1955). Testimony Brainard, Calvin H. "Statement in Opposition to Senate Bill States Senate. December 4, 1973. 354, The Federal No-Fault Automobile Insurance Act," Jeffers, Leroy. "Statement in Opposition to Senate Bill ­before the Committee on the Judiciary of the United 354, The Federal No-Fault Liability Insurance Act," States Senate. February 5, 1974. before the Committee on Commerce . of the United Griswold, Erwin N. Statement before the Committee on the States Senate. April 11, 1973. Judiciary of the United States Senate. January 30, 1974. Webb, Bernard L. "Cost Considerations Under the National Jeffers, Leroy. "Statement in Opposition to Senate Bill No-Fault Motor Vehicle Insurance Act (S.354)." A 354, The Federal No-Fault Automobile Insurance Act," statement before the Committee on the Judiciary of the before the Committee on the Judiciary of the United United States Senate. January 30, 1974. 69 Speeches Fournier, Frank W. Executive Director of the Automobile tive." An address before the National Conference on Accident Compensation Administration of Puerto Rico. Uniform State Laws. 1972. An Address to the National No-Fault Conference spon­Ingram, John R. Commissioner of Insurance, State of North sored by the Texas Association of Insurance Agents. Carolina. An address before the Communications Dallas, Texas, July 22, 1971. Workers of America, February 5, 1974. Keeton, Robert E. "No-Fault Developments in Perspec- Telephone Interviews Bartley, Nell. Medical Insurance Department, Brackenridge McDonald, Steve. A legal counsel with Blue Cross/Blue Hospital, Austin, Texas. Telephone interview, April 22, Shield of Texas. Telephone intel'View, April 23, 1974. 1974. Puryear, Jack. Nieman, Hanks, and Puryear, an Austin Hurt, Mildred. Texas State Board of Insurance. Telephone Insurance Company. Telephone interview, April 22, interview, April 22, 1974. 1974. Jenkins, Shirley. Boon-Chapman Insurance Managers of Washkoviac, Dennis. Royal Glove Insurance of Austin. Austin. Telephone interview, April 22, 1974. Telephone interview, April 22, 1974. Personal Interviews Frost, Robert. Staff Counsel, U.S. Senate · Commerce Walsh, Richard. Director, Office of Projects and Planning, Committee, Washington, D.C. Novem.ber 14, 1973. U.S. Department of Transportation, Washington, D.C. Graves, Janet. Milliman and Robertson, Consulting Actu­November 14, 1973. aries, Seattle, Washington. March, 1974. Guest Speakers Conner, Paul. Attorney-at-law, Austin, Texas. Formerly General Counsel, State Board of Insurance. Clines, Robert P. General Counsel, State Board of Insur· ance, Austin, Texas. November 20, 1973. Eisenberg, Jack, Wayne Fisher, and Windle Turley. Attor­neys-at-law, Texas Trial Lawyers Association. December 4, 1973. Howell, Hilton H. Attorney-at-law, Waco, Texas. President­Elect, Texas Association of Defense Counsel. February 5, 1974. Jeffers, Leroy. Attorney-at-law, Houston, Texas. President, State Bar of Texas, December 18, 1973. Perry, James. Law Department, State Farm Insurance Companies, Bloomington, Illinois. December 11, 1973. Roerink, Garrett M. Vice-President, Ranger Insurance Company, Houston, Texas. January 22, 1974. Tucker, Frank. Regional Vice-President, American Insur­ance Association, Dallas, Texas. November 13, 1973. 70 APPENDIX A COMPULSION/COMPLIANCE IN AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE: Survey Questionnaire · Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs The University of Texas at Austin Austin, Texas 78712 STATE: 1. Type of program. Indicate in the spaces provided the type of compulsory automobile insurance program you have (i.e., Bodily Injury Liability, Personal Injury Protection, etc.), the date that program was instituted, and the minimum amount of coverage required. Type of Program Date Instituted MinimumCoverage Requirea 2. Enforcement and Administration. a) Does the insurance department administer your compulsory program? Yes __No __. Ifnot, who does? b) Indicate below what change, if any, occurred in the number of personnel and in administrative costs as a result of the program. Type of Administrative ! Costs AdministrativeICosts Number of Personnel Number of Personnel Program the Year After the Year Before Year Before Year After ( c) What methods are used for discovery of noncompliance? d) Are penalties imposed for noncompliance? Yes __No__. Ifyes, please list the penalties. 71 3. Indicate the total number of cars and drivers in your state each of the five years before the program and each of the five years (ifapplicable) after the program. 4. Uninsured motorists. a) In your opinion, why do some drivers remain without coverage? Year Cars Drivers Cars Insured Drivers Insured b) Do you expect about the same number of uninsured motorists next year? Yes __No__. Why? c) What programs do you have to cover uninsured motorists? S. Describe briefly your program for guaranteeing the availability of insurance to high risk motorists. 6. Out-of-state motorists. a) Describe briefly your law with respect to out-of-state motorists. b) Describe briefly how residents are protected from uninsured out-of-state motorists, if not covered in a previous answer. 7. Indicate any other problems which you have encountered in attempting to administer your compulsory insurance law. a) Why, in your opinion, do these problems exist? b) What possible solutions to these problems have you undertaken or would you suggest? 8. Other comments or suggestions. 72 Survey Questionnaire 9. YourNarne·----------------------------.,..-----------------­ Title______________________'---------------------------~ Department'-------------..,......------------------------------~ Address._______________________________________________ Please mail the complete questionnaire to: Ms. Mary Lu Barras Automobile Insurance Seminar Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs, The University of Texas at Austin Drawer Y, University Station Austin, Texas 78712 73 APPENDIX B ACCIDENT QUESTIONNAIRE Lyndon B. Johnson School of Public Affairs The University of Texas at Austin Drawer Y, University Station Austin, Texas 78712 A. DETAILS OF THE ACCIDENT Yes No 1. Were you: a. riding in a privately owned automobile? b. riding in a commercial vehicle (taxi, etc.) c. riding on a motorcycle d. riding in a publicly owned vehicle (bus, etc.) e. a non-occupant (pedestrian or bicycle rider) 2. At the time of the accident, were you: a. the driver b. a passenger 3. How many cars were involved in the accident? a. l car b. More than one 4. Who was determined to be at fault in the accident? a. you b. another party c. fault unclear B. MEDICAL COSTS Yes No 5. As a result of this accident, did you receive treatment by a doctor? 6. How much were your hospital costs? $0-$100_, $101-$500_, $501-$1000_, 7. Other than any hospital bill, how much were the total medical costs for your care, including any amount paid by ·insurance (include cost of doctors, surgeon, dentists, private nurse, ambulance, medicine, special equipment such as wheel chairs, etc.)? (Check one) over $1000_. 74 $0-$100_, $101-$500_, $501.-$1000_, over $1 ooo__ . 8. If you were employed at the time of the accident, how long were you kept from work as a result of the accident? 0 days_, 1day-7days_,8-14 d~ys_, 15-30 days_, over 30 days_. 9. How much money in wages did you lose as a result of the accident? $0-$100_, $101-$500_, $501·$1000_, over $1000_. 10. If you were not employed at the time of the accident, how long were you kept from your usual activities because of the accident? 0 days_, 1 day-7days_, 8-14 days_, 15-30 days_, over 30 days_. 11. Did the accident leave yoµ with any permanent impairment which affects your ability to work or carry on other activities, such as school, housework or the like? __Yes __No. 12. Did the accident leave you with any permanent serious disfigurement? Yes __No __. 13. What amount (in dollars) of your hospital ~dmedical bills was paid by: a. Health insurance, including Medicare----­ b. Workmen's compensation c. Contributions and charity _________ d. Automobile insurance __________ e. Free medical expenses (military, etc.) _____ f. Your own pocket (do not include anything for which you were reimbursed) ________ g. Other (please specify)----'-------­ 14. What is the total amount of medical bills still unpaid? Accident Questionnaire 15. What sources did you use to meet your expenses, other than money from your own pocket? .· a. Savings __ b. Loan__ c. From sale of personal merchandise or property-­ d. Other (please specify) __ 16. Did you file a claim against someone or their insurance company for medical expenses or loss of income (not including car damage)? ___ 17. What was the amount of the claim? $ ____.____ 18. How much money did you receive (before deducting lawyer and other legal fees)? $ ________ 19. How soon after the accident was the first offer made to you to settle the claim? less than 10 days_, 11-30 days_, over 30 days_ 20. Did the insurance company make any advance pay­ments or pay any of the bills resulting from your injury before final settlement? Yes__No_. lfyes,howmuch? $______ D. LAWSUITS 21: Was a lawsuit for damages ever filed on your behalf as a result of an injury you received in this accident? __Yes__No 22. Did you hire a lawyer?_· _Yes __No 23. What agreement have you made with your lawyer regarding his fee: a. Percentage of the settlement __ b. Retainer or saiary __ l\ c. Other (Specify) __ 24. a. Was the case settled before the trial Ye!No started? .-_ b. Was the case settled before the trial was Yes No completed? -·-· c.was the cue Settied by the triiii verdict? Yes No 25. What were.your total legal expenses? $_____ 75 26. At the time of the accident, did you have liability pany as a result of the accident? __Ye& __No insurance, that is, insurance that will pay expenses of the other driver if you are at fault and damage his car 28. Suppose you had a choice of two kinds of auto insur­ or injure him? __Yes__ No ance that would.cost about the same, which would you prefer? 27. Was claim made against you or your insurance com- TYPEX TYPEY Pays for. ... Requires . .. . Payment by .... All expenses of the accident (including medical costs and loss of earnings). Sometimes an additional amount for pain and suffering. Establishing proof that other driver was at fault. Right to sue for auto injuries. The driver found at fault or his insurance company. All expenses of the accident (including medical costs and loss of earnings). No amount for pain and suffering. No need to establish proof that other driver was at fault. No right to sue for auto injuries. Insurance company of injured person. TypeY __ Don't Know __ TypeX -­ 76